Transcript Chapter 5
Chapter 5
Consumers and
Incentives
5 Consumers and Incentives
Chapter 5 Outline
5.1 The Buyer’s Problem
5.2 Putting It All Together
5.3 From the Buyer’s Problem to the Demand Curve
5.4 Consumer Surplus
5.5 Demand Elasticities
Key Ideas
1.
The buyer’s problem has three parts: what you like, prices, and your budget.
2.
An optimizing buyer makes decisions at the margin.
3.
An individual’s demand curve reflects an ability and willingness to pay for a good or
service.
4.
Consumer surplus is the difference between what a buyer is willing to pay for a good and
what the buyer actually pays.
5.
Elasticity measures a variable’s responsiveness to changes in another variable.
Why does the demand curve have a negative slope?
5.1 The Buyer’s Problem
1.
2.
3.
What do you like?
How much does it cost?
How much money do you
have?
5.1 The Buyer’s Problem What You Like: Tastes and Preferences
What do you like? Everyone has different likes and dislikes, but we assume everyone has
two things in common:
1.
We all want the “biggest bang for our buck”
2.
What we actually buy reflects our tastes and preferences
3
5.1 The Buyer’s Problem Prices of Goods and Services
How much does it cost?
We also assume two characteristics of prices:
1. Prices are fixed—no negotiation
2. We can buy as much as we want of something without driving the price up
(because of an increase in demand) – i.e. , as individual consumers, is too
small an influence on the overall market for our actions to have any
effect on the market price.
5.1 The Buyer’s Problem How Much Money You Have to Spend: The Budget Set
How much money do you have?
There are lots of things to do with your money, but we assume:
1.
There is no saving or borrowing, only buying
2.
That even though we use a straight line to represent purchase choices, we only purchase
whole units
4
5.1 The Buyer’s Problem How Much Money You Have to Spend: The Budget Set
Exhibit 5.1 The Budget Set and the
Budget Constraint for Your Shopping
Spree
If you have $300 to spend and all you
buy are jeans, which cost $50 a pair,
how many jeans can you buy? If all
you buy are sweaters at $25 each, how
many sweaters can you buy? Then
connect the dots.
Explore the three areas defined by this budget constraint:
1. Bundles on the line—combinations of jeans and sweaters that exactly spend $300.
2. Bundles inside the line (including buying no jeans and no sweaters)—bundles you can afford, but that
don’t spend your income. Remind students that there is no saving, so if the $300 is not spent, it is
lost—there is no other use for it than buying jeans and/or sweaters.
3. Bundles outside the constraint—these are bundles that you can’t afford (that would cost more than
$300). Remember there is no borrowing, so these bundles are unattainable.
Why does the budget line have a negative slope?
-- The negative slope represents trade-offs: if you want more of one thing, you have
5
to give up something else, as long as prices and income stay constant.
5.1 The Buyer’s Problem How Much Money You Have to Spend: The Budget Set
What does the slope represent?
The slope is = to the Pjeans/Psweaters.
6
5.2 Putting It All Together
Exhibit 5.2 Your Buyer’s Problem ($300 available)
The first sweater = 4; 1 jeans = 3.2; therefore, you should buy a sweater since it has greater marginal benefit per dollar than the first pair of jeans.
The second sweater = 3.4; first pair of jeans = 3.2; therefore, you should buy the second sweater for the same reason.
You now own 2 sweaters and 0 jeans.
The third sweater = 3; first pair of jeans = 3.2; therefore, you should buy the first pair of jeans.
You now own 2 sweaters and one pair of jeans.
We now look at the third sweater and the second pair of jeans: third sweater = 3; second pair of jeans = 3. You should buy both, but should you stop there?
No, because you still have money left (remember the only choice of what to do with your money is to spend it on these two goods).
You now own 3 sweaters and 2 pairs of jeans.
The fourth sweater = 2.6, and the third pair of jeans = 2. You should buy the sweater.
Continue in this way until you get to 6 sweaters and 3 pairs of jeans. Once again, the marginal benefit per dollar for each at that point is 2 and equal. At7this
point, you have spent $300.
5.2 Putting It All Together
Consumer Equilibrium Condition:
MBs = MBj
Ps
Pj
What if MBs = $75 and MBj = $100?
Remind yourself that equilibrium just means there is no incentive to change your
behavior. What would happen if the marginal benefit of another sweater were $75
and the marginal benefit of another pair of jeans was $100. The ratio would be 3 for
sweaters and 2 for jeans.
Suppose you get more bang for your buck with sweaters, is there an incentive to
change your behavior? Yes, you would buy more sweaters. The incentive to change
your behavior goes away when the two ratios are equal.
If the ratio is 3 to 2 and they have an incentive to buy another sweater, what
happens to the ratio?
When you buy another sweater, the marginal benefit of that sweater is less than
that of the previous sweater (because of diminishing marginal benefit), so it is less
than $75, bringing it back to equilibrium.
8
5.2 Putting It All Together Price Changes
Suppose the price of sweaters doubles, to $50. Before, the price of sweaters was $25
and the price of jeans was $50. You asked how many sweaters they could buy with
their $300 if they didn’t buy any jeans and their answer was 12. If they only bought
jeans, they could buy 6.
Looking at the original line, ask them what would happen if the price of sweaters
doubles, to $50. If they only buy sweaters, how many can they buy? The answer is
6. Ask what that looks like on the original graph—the budget constraint pivots on
the jeans axis (horizontal).
Now ask what would happen if instead, the price of jeans decreases to $25. If they
buy only jeans (no sweaters), they can buy 12 pairs. Ask how the graph would9
change (the budget constraint would pivot on the vertical axis—the sweater axis).
5.2 Putting It All Together Price Changes
The new budget constraint reflects the increase in the price of sweaters—and the
line pivots on the other good.
At the new price of sweaters, ask how many jeans must be given up if you want
another sweater..
Exhibit 5.3 An Inward Pivot in the Budget Constraint from a Price Increase
10
5.2 Putting It All Together Price Changes
Notice how the graph changes when the price of jeans decreased. Again, the budget
constraint pivots on the axis with the other good and again, the opportunity cost
changes.
Exhibit 5.4 A Rightward Pivot in the Budget Constraint from a Price Decrease
11
5.2 Putting It All Together Income Changes
Return to the original condition of the price of a sweater = $25 and the price of jeans = $50.
What would happen if they had $600 instead of $300. Again, if all they buy is sweaters, they
could now afford 24; jeans, 12.
The slope of the line does not change because the ratio of the prices hasn’t changed (and that
means opportunity cost doesn’t change), so the budget constraint shifts out in parallel
fashion.
Exhibit 5.5 An Outward Shift in the Budget Constraint from an Increase in Income
12
5.3 From the Buyer’s Problem to the Demand Curve
Quantity
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
Total
Benefits
Sweaters $25
Marginal
Benefits
(A)
(B)
0
100
185
260
325
385
435
480
520
555
589
622
654.5
100
85
75
65
60
50
45
40
35
34
33
32.5
Marginal
Benefits
per Dollar
Spent =
(B) / $25
4
3.4
3
2.6
2.4
2
1.8
1.6
1.4
1.36
1.32
1.3
Total
Benefits
(C)
0
160
310
410
490
520
530
533
535
536
537
538
539
Jeans $50
Marginal
Marginal
Benefits
Benefits
per Dollar
Spent =
(D)
(D) / $50
160
150
100
80
30
10
3
2
1
1
1
1
3.2
3
2
1.6
0.6
0.2
0.06
0.04
0.02
0.02
0.02
0.02
Marginal
Benefits
per Dollar
Spent =
(D) / $75
2.13
2
1.33
1.07
0.4
0.13
0.04
0.03
0.01
0.01
-0.02
-0.07
Go back to the table with marginal benefits (Exhibit 5.2).
when the price of jeans is $50, the optimal quantity of jeans is 3.
what happens to the optimal number of jeans if the price of jeans increases to $75.
look carefully at the table on this slide and notice that the last column has changed (the values
have decreased) because the price of jeans has increased.
Perform the same kind of analysis as before, with the result that when the price is $75, the
optimum quantity of jeans is 2.
If you want, you can change this column a few more times with different prices of jeans,
getting various optimal quantities. These results are summarized in the next slide.
13
5.3 From the Buyer’s Problem to the Demand Curve
Why does a soda machine only dispense one bottle or can at a time, but
a newspaper vending machine opens up so that you can take as many as
you want?
Idea: marginal benefit: the marginal benefit of an additional
newspaper is zero—there’s no incentive to take another one. But
the marginal benefit of another bottle of pop is (probably)
14
positive.
5.4 Consumer Surplus
Consumer Surplus -The difference between what you are willing to pay and what you have
to pay (the market price)
Summing across all
the individual
demand curves gives
us a market curve,
along with a market
consumer surplus.
We can get an exact
measure by using the
formula for the area of
a triangle.
Exhibit 5.8 Market-Wide Consumer Surplus
15
5.4 Consumer Surplus An Empty Feeling: Loss in Consumer Surplus When Price
Increases
When the price of a good increases, there are fewer people who are willing to pay more than
the market price. Therefore, consumer surplus falls.
So when the price of a good increases, for whatever reason, the added benefit to consumers
(overall) falls.
Likewise, when the price decreases, consumer surplus increases, increasing the overall welfare
of consumers.
Exhibit 5.9 Market-Wide Consumer Surplus When Prices Change
16
5 Consumers and Incentives
Your Buyer’s Problem with an Extra $100 ($300 → $400)
Compare this table to the original—the marginal benefits and the marginal benefits per
dollar are the same. What’s different is that now you have $400 to spend instead of $300.
So the optimal bundle of sweaters and jeans has changed.
One can now buy 8 sweaters (before it was 6) and 4 pairs of jeans (before it was 3 pairs).
Accepting the $100 per month to quit smoking means that you can consume 2 more
sweaters and 1 more pair of jeans.
17
5.4 Demand Elasticities
Suppose you play in a band. Your band has a steady gig with a bar that gives
you the cover charge without taking a cut. You and your band are interested in
increasing the money you make from this gig and are talking about changing
the cover charge.
Should you increase it or decrease it?
The Issue
we know from the law of demand that if price increases, quantity
demanded decreases and vice-versa. So one option is to increase the
cover charge, making more from each person who comes in but
knowing that fewer people will attend.
The other option is to decrease the price, knowing that more people
will attend but that you will be making less from each person. Both
options make sense and are reasoned correctly. But only one can be
correct.
18
5.4 Demand Elasticities
Elasticity- A measure of how sensitive one variable is to changes in another
Three measures of elasticity:
1. Price elasticity of demand
2. Cross-price elasticity of demand
3. Income elasticity of demand
5.4 Demand Elasticities -The Price Elasticity of Demand
1. Price elasticity of demand answers the question:
How much does quantity demanded change when the good’s price changes?
Mathematically: the percentage change in quantity demanded due to a percentage
change in price:
19
5.4 Demand Elasticities Price Elasticity of Demand
Jeans example from Exhibit 5.6:
The lowest price was $25, and the optimal quantity was 4 pairs.
The second price was $50, and the optimal quantity was 3 pairs.
Quantity decreased by 25% ((4-3)/4) when price increased by 100% ((2550)/25), so
ED = -25%/100% = -0.25
20
5.4 Demand Elasticities Elasticity Measures
ED > 1
ED < 1
ED = 1
ED = ∞
ED = 0
= Elastic
= Inelastic
= Unit Elastic
= Perfectly Elastic
= Perfectly Inelastic
The jeans example returned an elasticity of 0.25 (remind them to ignore the
negative sign), so that makes the price elasticity of demand for jeans inelastic.
What does that mean? Remember how that number was computed: price
increased by 100%, but the effect on the quantity was not nearly that much—
only 25%. So people don’t respond very much (in terms of their demand for
jeans) when the price changes.
If demand is elastic, people are pretty responsive to price changes and will
change their quantity demanded quite a bit. With perfectly elastic demand,
any change in price means that consumers stop purchasing completely. And
perfectly inelastic means that no matter what the price is, consumers will buy
the same amount. These two extremes are more theoretical than practical,
although they will be seeing perfectly elastic demand functions in an
upcoming chapter.
21
5.4 Demand Elasticities
Elasticity Measures
Exhibit 5.13 Examples of Various Price Elasticities
22
5.4 Demand Elasticities
Suppose you play in a band. Your band has a steady
gig with a bar that gives you the cover charge without
taking a cut.
You and your band are interested in increasing the
money you make from this gig and are talking about
changing the cover charge.
Should you increase it or decrease it?
23
5.4 Demand Elasticities
TR = P x Q
If demand is inelastic, when price increases, quantity decreases—a
little:
TR =
Px Q=
TR
The price increase pushes total revenue up, the quantity decrease
pushes total revenue down, but the price increase is more than the
quantity decrease, so the final result is that total revenue increases.
TR = P x Q
If price decreases, total revenue also decreases. As a result of the
lower price, quantity increases, but because demand is inelastic,
quantity increases only slightly. The net result on total revenue is that
it decreases.
TR =
P x
Q=
TR
24
5.4 Demand Elasticities Determinants of the Price Elasticity of Demand
Determinants:
Number and closeness of substitutes
Budget share spent on the good
Time horizon available to adjust to price changes
25
5.4 Demand Elasticities Determinants of the Price Elasticity of Demand
(a). Why are last-minute airplane tickets so expensive?
(b). Why are last-minute Broadway show tickets so cheap?
Key: Think of the determinants of elasticity, particularly
substitutes. If someone needs to get somewhere quickly, there
are no substitutes for flying there. But there are many substitutes
for Broadway show tickets—there are a lot of other things to do
in New York City, so people will be more responsive to the price.
26
5.4 Demand Elasticities The Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand
2. Cross-price elasticity of demand answers the question:
How much does the quantity demanded of one good change
when the price of another good changes?
Mathematically: the percentage change in demand of good 1 due to a
percentage change in the price of good 2:
Note: In the case of cross-price elasticity, both the sign and the magnitude are important.
If the answer is positive that the goods are substitutes. If it is negative, it means
that the goods are complements.
The magnitude of the elasticity is a measure of how strong the relationship is
between the two goods. A cross-price elasticity of 0.05 indicates a very weak
relationship, for example. The closer the measure is to zero, the more likely it is that
they actually have no relationship at all.
27
5.4 Demand Elasticities The Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand
Exhibit 5.14 Examples of Various Cross-Price Elasticities
28
5.4 Demand Elasticities The Income Elasticity of Demand
3. Income elasticity of demand answers the question:
How much does quantity demanded change when income changes?
Mathematically: the percentage change in demand of a good due to a
percentage change in income
Again, both the sign and magnitude are important here. If the sign is positive, it
means that an increase in income is causing an increase in demand, meaning that
the good is a normal good.
The opposite holds for inferior goods. Again, remind students that this
relationship has been discussed before; the addition of elasticity just allows us to
talk about measuring that relationship.
The magnitude, again, measures the strength of the relationship.
29
5.4 Demand Elasticities The Income Elasticity of Demand
Exhibit 5.15 Examples of Various Income Elasticities
30