The Economics of Marging Squeeze
Download
Report
Transcript The Economics of Marging Squeeze
1
Margin Squeeze under EC Competition Law
organized by GCLC and BT
London, 10 December 2004
The Economics of
Margin Squeeze
A short history of
nearly everything
Dr. Jorge Padilla
Managing Director
LECG Europe
Brussels-London-Madrid-Paris
1
2
Introduction
Positive economics:
What is a margin squeeze?
Normative economics:
What is the impact on consumer welfare?
Using economics to design administrable
intervention rules:
How to catch an anti-competitive margin
squeeze?
2
3
Positive economics
3
4
What’s a margin squeeze?
Definition:
A vertically integrated firm
holding a dominant position in the
upstream market prevents its
(non-vertically integrated)
downstream competitors from
achieving an economically viable
price-cost margin.
U
w
D1
D2
p1
p2
Consumers
Margin = Retail Price – Wholesale Price < Downstream Costs
4
5
What’s a margin squeeze?
Predation:
It can do so by charging a
downstream price that is too
low relative to the input
price, with the result of driving
out some or all downstream
rivals, or at least significantly
weakening their competitive
positions.
U
w
D1
D2
p1
p2
Consumers
Retail Price < Downstream Costs + Wholesale price
5
6
What’s a margin squeeze?
Vertical foreclosure /
Refusal to deal:
It can do so by charging a
wholesale price that is too
high relative to the
downstream price, with the
result of driving out some or
all downstream rivals, or at
least significantly weakening
their competitive positions.
U
w
D1
D2
p1
p2
Consumers
Retail Price – Downstream Costs < Wholesale Price
6
7
Nihil novum sub sole
Margin squeeze
Margin = Retail Price – Wholesale Price < Downstream Costs
Predation
Retail Price < Downstream Costs + Wholesale price
Refusal to deal
Retail Price – Downstream Costs < Wholesale Price
7
8
The sacrifice fallacy
The claim that margin squeeze is different than predation
because it involves no sacrifice is incorrect
True p1 < w implies no direct
losses for vertically integrated firm
U
w
But there is an opportunity cost, w,
for each unit not sold to downstream
competitor
And that opportunity cost may be
very large when the wholesale price
is above the upstream marginal cost
And even larger if D2 sells
differentiated products and/or is more
cost efficient – Chicago critique
D1
D2
p1
p2
Consumers
8
9
Anticompetitive motivations
Monopolization of downstream market, or relaxation
of competition in downstream market
Salop and Scheffman, JIE, 1987
Restoring market power upstream
Rey and Tirole, Handbook of IO, forthcoming 2005
Defensive leveraging
Carlton and Waldman, RAND JE, 2000
9
10
Showing margin squeeze is not enough
Ability:
Market power upstream and downstream
Barriers to entry and re-entry
Asymmetries between predator and prey
o Informational asymmetries
• Signaling
• Reputation effects
o Financial asymmetries
Incentives:
Upstream losses
o Regulated prices upstream
o Business stealing effect
10
11
Pro-competitive justifications
Predation:
Aggressive competition – meeting the competition
Dynamic pricing in markets with switching costs,
network externalities, experience or credence goods …
Refusal to deal:
Static efficiency – free riding in the provision of
services, quality certification, etc.
Dynamic efficiency – profitability of ex ante
investments
11
12
A “plain vanilla” static analysis is
necessarily misleading
In many markets, privately and socially optimal pricing
policies are dynamic: current losses, overall positive
profits
Present
Current losses
cannot constitute
evidence of intent or
likely exclusionary
effect in emerging
markets
Future
Total
Revenues
Costs
12
13
Any sensible approach implies assumptions
about future revenues and costs
Discounted Cash Flows
Future
Total
Revenues
Time evolution of prices
Excluding anti-competitive
profits
Costs
Inter-temporal allocation of start
up costs
o Infrastructure costs
o Customer acquisition costs
Time evolution of costs
o Economies of scale
o Learning by doing, etc.
13
14
Normative economics
14
15
Welfare implications
Allocative versus productive efficiency
It may be efficient to exclude “as efficient”
competitors and exclude “as efficient” entrants
o Excessive entry, excessive variety
But it may also be efficient to allow entry of
“inefficient” competitors
Static versus dynamic efficiency
Ex ante incentives to innovate and invest
15
16
Designing administrable rules
16
17
Administrable rules
Alternative legal standards:
Per se rules
Rule of reason
Hybrid rules:
o Modified per se rules
o Structured rule of reason
Selection criteria:
Minimizing the expected cost of error
Be cheap to administer
Give economic agents predictability
17
18
Administrable rules
Choosing the right rule:
Per se rules don’t work
Rule of reason is very difficult and bound to lead
to erroneous decisions
Options:
Structured rule of reason: 3 stages
Rebuttable presumptions:
o Imputation test?
Modified per se rules:
o Exceptional circumstances test?
18
19
Administrable rules
The costs of type I and type II errors:
Price
Supply
Dynamic Loss=A
Static Loss=B+C
A
Price
Cost
B
C
Demand
Quantity
19
20
Administrable rules
The likelihood of type I versus type II errors:
Likelihood of error is high
• Dynamic price-cost tests conducted ex post
• Debate over appropriate cost standard in static tests
• Pro-competitive explanations
• Confusing foreclosure with industry shakeouts
20
21
Conclusions
Nihil Novum Sub Sole
Any sensible approach implies assumptions
about future revenues and costs
From a competition policy perspective,
showing a price squeeze is not enough
There is a need for clear, efficient and
administrable rules; economics has a role to
play in this process
21
22
The Economics of Margin Squeeze
A short history of nearly everything
Dr. Jorge Padilla
Managing Director
[email protected]
LECG Europe
Brussels: +32 2 517 6070
London: + 44 207 269 0500
Madrid: + 34 91 594 7979
Paris: + 33 1 5 568 1280
www.lecgcp.com
22