April 6 - UCSB Economics
Download
Report
Transcript April 6 - UCSB Economics
Public goods
Today: What is a public good?
Efficient provision
Public versus private provision
Beginning Unit 2
Last time
We concluded our “tools” lectures
End of Unit 1
Today
Begin Unit 2
Public goods (Chapter 4)
What is a public good?
Efficient provision
Public versus private provision
Public goods
Public goods are goods that have some
degree of two characteristics
Nonrival
Nonexcludable
These two characteristics lead to suboptimal
consumption when public goods are privately
purchased
Externalities involved, to be defined later
Definitions
Nonrival good (R/G p. 54)
“Once it is provided, the
additional resource cost of
another person consuming the
good is zero”
Nonexcludable good (R/G p.
54)
“To prevent anyone from
consuming the good is either
very expensive or impossible”
Pure public good
(R/G p. 54)
“A commodity that
is nonrival and
nonexcludable in
consumption”
Categories of goods
Excludable
Rival
High
Low
Low
Commons good
(oxygen that you
breathe)
Public good
(lighthouses)
High
Private good
(pens)
Collective good
(copyrighted books)
Categories of goods
Excludable
Rival
High
Low
Low
Commons good
(oxygen that you
breathe)
Public good
(lighthouses)
High
Private good
(pens)
Collective good
(copyrighted books)
Covered in Econ 1; uses basic supply/demand theory
Categories of goods
Excludable
Rival
High
Low
Low
Commons good
(oxygen that you
breathe)
Public good
(lighthouses)
High
Private good
(pens)
Collective good
(copyrighted books)
Often covered in Econ 1 or Econ 100B
Categories of goods
Excludable
Rival
High
Low
Low
Commons good
(oxygen that you
breathe)
Public good
(lighthouses)
High
Private good
(pens)
Collective good
(copyrighted books)
Goods with copyright or patent protection have some level of market power
Other examples of public goods
Basic research
Programs to fight poverty
Uncongested nontoll roads
Fireworks displays
Noteworthy aspects of public goods
Even though everyone consumes the same
quantity of the good, it need not be valued
equally by all
Surfers generally value ocean quality more than
people living in Utah
Classification as a public good is not
absolute; it depends on market conditions
and the state of technology
Impure public goods are “rival and/or excludable
to some extent” (R/G p. 53)
Noteworthy aspects of public goods
Some things that are not conventionally
thought of as commodities have public good
characteristics
Restaurant ratings
Consistent within a city
Often different standards between cities
Example: It appears easier to get an “A” rating in San
Diego County than in Los Angeles County
Noteworthy aspects of public goods
Private goods are not necessarily provided
exclusively by the private sector
Publicly provided private goods
Example: Government-provided food for the poor
Public provision of a good does not
necessarily mean that it is also produced by
the public sector
Many publicly-provided services are contracted to
private firms
Example: Defense-related goods
Demand of private goods
Demand of private goods are summed
horizontally
Add the quantity demanded for each person at a
given price
Efficient Provision of Private Goods
Price
$11
Adam
(DfA)
5
Eve
(DfA)
1
Market
(DfA+E)
6
$9
7
3
10
$7
9
5
14
$5
11
7
18
$3
13
9
22
$1
15
11
26
$
12
11
10
Sf
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
DfA+E
2
1
DfE
0
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
DfA
9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26
Quantity of Pizza
Equilibrium and efficiency, private goods
Privately-provided goods have optimal levels
produced if the following conditions are met:
The goods are private
Rival and excludable
Competitive markets
No market power exists
Price and quantity are where demand and supply curves
meet
Public goods
We will examine pure public goods
Highly nonrival
Highly nonexcludable
Marginal analysis is used to find the optimal
quantity
Optimal quantity is where PUBLIC MB equals MC
An example: Fireworks
Units of Fireworks
1
2
3
4
Adam (DfA)
$300
$250
$200
$150
Eve (DfE)
$250
$200
$150
$100
Market
(DfA+E)
$550
$450
$350
$250
$
800
750
700
650
600
550
500
450
Sf
400
350
300
250
200
150
DfA+E
DfA
100
50
0
DfE
1
2
3
Quantity of Fireworks
4
Kinks
Some public MB curves
have a kink in them
Why?
Notice that person B
starts having a
willingness to pay of 0 at
a lower quantity than
person A
Another example
Fireworks show off of a tiny coastal community
25 people live here
Each person has the same private demand for fireworks
P = 2 – 0.08 Q
MC for fireworks is 10
Notice that if fireworks were privately purchased,
nobody would buy them (10 > 2)
Fireworks show as a public good
Since one person’s enjoyment of fireworks
does not take away from the enjoyment from
others, PUBLIC MB is the sum of PRIVATE
MBs
PUBLIC MB is the vertical summation of all
25 PRIVATE MBs
Public MB = 25 (2 – 0.08 Q) = 50 – 2Q
Vertical summation
Vertical
summation of
25 PRIVATE
MB lines
produces
PUBLIC MB
line
PUBLIC
MB
MC
Vertical
intercept is 50
PRIVATE MB
Marginal analysis
To find efficient level of fireworks, set PUBLIC
MB = MC
50 – 2Q = 10
Q = 20
Free rider problem
When public goods are provided privately,
some people let others buy the good for their
own enjoyment
These people are known as free riders
Perfect price discrimination can solve the free
rider problem
Usually cannot be done, since it requires
knowledge of each person’s demand curve for the
public good
Do people free ride?
Public goods games
Inefficient results predicted
Experimental economics tests free rider
theories
A public goods game
You can decide whether or not you want to
contribute to a new flower garden at a local
park
If you decide Yes, you will lose $200, but every
person in the city you live in will gain $10 in
benefits from the park
If you decide No, you will cause no change to the
outcome of you or other people
A public goods game
What is each person’s best response, given
the decision of others?
We need to look at each person’s marginal
gain and loss (if any)
Choose yes Gain $10, lose $200
Choose no Gain $0, lose $0
A public goods game
Which is the better choice?
Choose no (Gain nothing vs. net loss of $190)
Nash equilibrium has everybody choosing no
Efficient outcome has everybody choosing
yes
Why the difference?
Each person does not account for others’ benefits
when making their own decision
Experimental economics
Experiments are conducted approximately as
follows
A group of people meet in a classroom
Each person is offered money (or the equivalent
of money)
Each person has the opportunity to donate money
to a fund
There is a “money multiplier”
Money (after multiplied) gets distributed equally to
everyone in the classroom
Public goods experiments
Typical results of public goods experiments
People contribute about 50% of resources to provision of
public good
Contributions fall the more often the game is repeated
More cooperation with prior communication
Contribution rates decline when opportunity cost of giving
goes up
“Warm-glow” giving
Some people may feel good by improving social welfare
Public versus private provision of a good
Although public goods are often publicly
financed, there is often debate as to whether
or not the public sector should also provide
the good
There are a few criteria that help to determine
provision
Relative wage and materials costs
Administrative costs
Diversity of tastes
Commodity egalitarianism
Provision criteria
Relative wage and materials costs
Public sector workers are often unionized more,
leading to higher costs than in the private sector
Administrative costs
Often lower if service provided by public sector
Public administration is already set up MC of
additional administration is low
Provision criteria
Diversity of tastes
Private provision often means more options to the
consumer
Distributional issues
Is there a minimum amount of schooling and
health care that should be provided to everyone?
Up to personal preference and debate
Public/private provision debate
Change of provision between public and
private sectors
Heavily debated in some cases
Some issues
Uncertainty
Responsibility of fulfilling services
Quality of good or service
Incomplete contracts in some private sector services
Example: All contingencies for security contracts
Consumer satisfaction within a market
Private provision of national defense
Example: Substantial amounts of money are
spent on national defense
9.3% of GDP in 1962 (Cold War era)
3.4% of GDP in 1997
Many goods and services related to national
defense are privately provided
The type of contract could lead to substantial
changes in cost to government
Private provision of national defense
Big private contracts to provide national
defense involve substantial risk
Cost of cutting-edge technology is very uncertain
Fixed price contracts leave all the risk on the firm
Cost-plus contracts often lead to substantial cost
overruns
Winner’s curse
No incentives to keep costs down
What else can be used?
Incentive contracts
Incentive contracts
Incentive contracts incorporate aspects of fixed price
and cost-plus contracts
Department of Defense pays a fixed fee plus a
fraction of production costs
TC = F + λ C
When 0 < λ < 1…
There is an economic incentive to the firm to prevent cost
overruns
The firm bears less risk than with fixed price contracts
Special cases
λ = 0 Fixed price contract
λ = 1 and F = 0 Cost-plus contract
Who decides how much to provide?
Somebody in government must make
decisions about public goods
More on decision making in Chapter 6
Political economy
Summary
Public goods are nonrival and nonexcludable
in consumption
Demand of public goods uses vertical
summation
Free rider problem predicts suboptimal
quantities purchased
Mixed evidence from experimental economics
Ongoing debate between public and private
provision of public goods
Another example
Patty and Selma are the only two people that
enjoy grass in a Shelbyville park
Cost to plant an acre of grass is $70
Patty’s demand for grass is P = 100 – 10Q
Selma’s demand for grass is P = 300 – 20Q
Assume that grass is a public good in this park
Patty and Selma
If Patty and Selma were left to purchasing
grass on their own as a private good…
Patty: 70 = 100 – 10Q Q = 3
Selma: 70 = 300 – 20Q Q = 11.5
Patty and Selma
Since grass is a public good, we should let
Patty and Selma spend money for grass that
they can both use
Vertical summation of willingness to pay (WTP)
WARNING: Be careful when calculating, since
there is a kink
When P is 0 for Patty, Q is 10 Patty has WTP of 0 for
additional acres above 10
When P is 0 for Selma, Q is 15 Selma has WTP of 0
for additional acres above 15
Vertical summation for Patty and Selma
For quantities between 0 and 10, we sum
each person’s WTP to determine public
marginal benefit for each additional acre
Public MB = (100 – 10Q) + (300 – 20Q)
Public MB = 400 – 30Q
For quantities between 10 and 15, Selma is
the only person with a positive WTP
Public MB = 300 – 20Q
Calculating the efficient quantity
Two steps
Plug in MC in both equations
Find which answer matches the relevant quantity range
Step 1
For Q between 0-10
For Q between 10-15
70 = 400 – 30Q Q = 11
70 = 300 – 20Q Q = 11.5
Step 2
Pick the second quantity (10 < 11.5 < 15)
What if MC is 130?
Step 1
For Q between 0-10
For Q between 10-15
130 = 400 – 30Q Q = 9
130 = 300 – 20Q Q = 8.5
Step 2
Pick the first quantity (0 < 9 < 10)
Next week
Externalities
Read Chapter 5
Positive and negative externalities
Graphical analysis
Deadweight loss (or excess burden)
Bargaining and other private responses
Public responses
Taxes
Subsidies
Permits
Have a good weekend