Transcript Document
Vertical and Conglomerate
Mergers
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
1
Introduction
• General Electric and Honeywell proposed to merge in
2000
– GE supplies jet engines for commercial aircraft
– Honeywell produced various electrical and other control systems
for jet aircraft
• Deal was approved in the US
• But was blocked by the EU Competition Directorate
– this was a merger of complementary firms
– it is “like” a vertical merger
– so can potentially remove inefficiencies in pricing
• benefiting the merged firms and consumers
– so why block the merger?
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
2
Introduction 2
• Vertical mergers can be detrimental
– if they facilitate market foreclosure by the merged firms
• refuse to supply non-merged rivals
• But they can also be beneficial
– if they remove market inefficiencies
• Regulators need to look for the balance these two forces in
considering any proposed merger
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
3
Complementary Mergers
• Consider first a merger between firms that supply
complementary products
• A simple example:
–
–
–
–
–
–
final production requires two inputs in fixed proportions
one unit of each input is needed to make one unit of output
input producers are monopolists
final product producer is a monopolist
demand for the final product is P = 140 - Q
marginal costs of upstream producers and final producer (other
than for the two inputs) normalized to zero.
• What is the effect of merger between the two upstream
producers?
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
4
Complementary mergers 2
Supplier 1
Supplier 2
price v2
price v1
Final Producer
price P
Consumers
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
5
Complementary producers
Consider the profit of the final producer: this is
pf = (P - v1 - v2)Q = (140 - v1 - v2 - Q)Q
Solve this for Q
Maximize this with respect to Q
pf/Q = 140 - (v1 + v2) - 2Q = 0
Q = 70 - (v1 + v2)/2
This gives us the demand for each input
Q1 = Q2 = 70 - (v1 + v2)/2
So the profit of supplier 1 is then: p1 = v1Q1 = v1(70 - v1/2 - v2/2)
Maximize this with respect to v1
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
6
Complementary
producers 2
The price charged by
each supplier is a
p1 = v1Q1 = v1(70 - v1/2 - v2/2) Solve this for v
function of the other We need to
1 solve
supplier’s
Maximize this with respect
to v1 price these two pricing
equations
1
p /v1 = 70 - v1 - v2/2 = 0
v1 = 70 - v2/2
We can do exactly the same for v2
v2 = 70 - v1/2
v1 = 70 - (70 - v1/2)/2 = 35 + v1/4
so 3v1/4 = 35 so v1 = $46.67
v2
140
R1
70
46.67
R2
and v2 = $46.67
46.67 70
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
140
v1
7
Complementary products 3
Recall that Q = Q1 = Q2 = 70 - (v1 + v2)/2
so Q = Q1 = Q2 = 23.33 units
The final product price is P = 140 - Q = $116.67
Profits of the three firms are then:
supplier 1 and supplier 2: p1 = p2 = 46.67 x 23.33 = $1,088.81
final producer: pf = (116.67 - 46.67 - 46.67) x 23.33 = $544.29
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
8
Complementary products 4
Supplier 1
Now suppose that the
two suppliers merge Supplier 2
23.33 units @
$46.67 each
23.33 units @
$46.67 each
Final Producer
23.33 units @ $116.67 each
Consumers
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
9
Complementary mergers 5
Supplier 1
Supplier 2
price v
The merger allows the
two firms to coordinate
their prices
Final Producer
price P
Consumers
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
10
Complementary merger 6
Consider the profit of the final producer: this is
pf = (P - v)Q = (140 - v - Q)Q
Maximize this with respect to Q
Solve this for
Q
pf/Q = 140 - v - 2Q = 0
Q = 70 - v/2
This gives us the demand for each input
Q1 = Q2 = Qm = 70 - v/2
So the profit of the merged supplier is: pm = vQm = v(70 - v/2)
Maximize this with respect to v
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
11
Complementary merger 7
This is the cost of the combined
pm = vQm = v(70 - v/2)
input: the merger has reduced
costs to the final producer
Differentiate with respect to v
The merger has reduced
the final product price:
pm/v = 70 - v = 0 so v = $70
consumers gain
Recall that Qm = Q = 70 - v/2 so Qm = Q = 35 units
This is greater than the
combined
This gives the final product price
P = 140 -pre-merger
Q = $105
profit
What about profits? For the merged upstream firm:
This is greater than the
m
p = vQm = 70 x 35 = $2,480
pre-merger profit
For the final producer:
pf = (105 - 70) x 35 = $1,225
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
12
Complementary mergers 8
• A merger of complementary producers has
– increased profits of the merged firms
– increased profit of the final producer
– reduced the price charged to consumers
Everybody gains from this merger: a Pareto improvement! Why?
• This merger corrects a market failure
– prior to the merger the upstream suppliers do not take full account
of their interdependence
– reduction in price by one of them reduces downstream costs,
increases downstream output and benefits the other upstream firm
– but this is an externality and so is ignored
• Merger internalizes the externality
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
13
Vertical Mergers
• The same result arises when we consider vertical mergers:
mergers of upstream and downstream firms
• If the merging firms have market power
– lack of co-ordination in their independent decisions
– double marginalization
– merger can lead to a general improvement
• Illustrate with a simple model
– one upstream and one downstream monopolist
• manufacturer and retailer
–
–
–
–
upstream firm has marginal costs c
sells product to the retailer at price r per unit
retailer has no other costs: one unit of input gives one unit of output
retail demand is P = A – BQ
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
14
Vertical merger 2
Marginal
costs c
Manufacturer
wholesale price r
Price P
Consumer Demand: P = A - BQ
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
15
Vertical merger 3
• Consider the retailer’s decision
– identify profit-maximizing output
– set the profit maximizing price
Price
A
Demand
marginal revenue downstream is
MR = A – 2BQ
marginal cost is r
equate MC = MR to give the
quantity Q = (A - r)/2B
identify the price from the demand
curve: P = A - BQ = (A + r)/2
profit to the retailer is (P - r)Q
which is pD = (A - r)2/4B
(A+r)/2
r
profit to the manufacturer is (r-c)Q
which is pM = (r - c)(A - r)/2B
MC
A-r
2B
MR
A/2B
A/B
Quantity
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
16
Vertical merger 4
suppose the manufacturer sets a
different price r1
then the downstream firm’s
output choice changes to the output
Q1 = (A - r1)/2B
Price
A
Demand
r1
demand for the manufacturer’s
output is just the downstream
marginal revenue curve
r
A-r
A - r1
and so on for other input prices
MC
Upstream demand
MR
Quantity
A/2B
A/B
2B
2B
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
17
Vertical merger 5
the manufacturer’s marginal cost is c
upstream demand is Q = (A - r)/2B which
is r = A – 2BQ
upstream marginal revenue is, therefore,
MRu = A – 4BQ
equate MRu = MC: A – 4BQ = c
Price
A
(3A+c)/4
Demand
(A+c)/2
Upstream demand
c
MRu
A/4B
MR
A/2B
MC
A/B
so Q*=(A-c)/4B the input price is (A+c)/2
while the consumer price is (3A+c)/4
the manufacturer’s profit is (A-c)2/8B
the retailer’s profit is (A-c)2/16B
Quantity
(A-c)/4B
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
18
Vertical merger 6
• Now suppose that the retailer and manufacturer merge
–
–
–
–
manufacturer takes over the retail outlet
retailer is now a downstream division of an integrated firm
the integrated firm aims to maximize total profit
Suppose the upstream division sets an internal (transfer) price of r
for its product
– Suppose that consumer demand is P = P(Q)
The internal transfer
– Total profit is:
price nets out of the
• upstream division: (r - c)Q
• downstream division: (P(Q) - r)Q
• aggregate profit: (P(Q) - c)Q
profit calculations
• Back to the example
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
19
Vertical merger 7
This merger has
the integrated demand is P(Q) = A - BQ
benefited theThis
two merger has
marginal revenue is MR = A – 2BQ
firmsbenefited consumers
Price
marginal cost is c
so the profit-maximizing output requires
that A – 2BQ = c
so Q* = (A – c)/2B
so the retail price is P = (A + c)/2
A
Demand
(A+c)/2
aggregate profit of the integrated firm is
(A – c)2/4B
c
MR
(A-c)/4B
MC
A/B
Quantity
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
20
Vertical merger 8
• Integration increases profits and consumer surplus
• Why?
– the firms have some degree of market power
– so they price above marginal cost
– so integration corrects a market failure: double marginalization
• What if manufacture were competitive?
– retailer plays off manufacturers against each other
– so obtains input at marginal cost
– gets the integrated profit without integration
• Why worry about vertical integration?
– two possible reasons
• price discrimination
• vertical foreclosure
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
21
Price discrimination
• Upstream firm selling to two downstream markets
– different demands in the two markets
v1
the seller wants to price
discriminate between these
markets
set v1 < v2
v2
va
Market 1
P
Market 2
P
D1
D2
Q
Q
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
but suppose that buyers
can arbitrage
then buyer 2 offers to buy
from buyer 1 at a price va
such that v1 < va < v2
arbitrage prevents price
discrimination
if the seller integrates
into market 1 arbitrage is
prevented
22
Vertical foreclosure
• Vertically integrated firm refuses to supply other firms
– so integration can eliminate competitors
suppose that the seller is supplying
three firms with an essential input
the seller integrates with one buyer
if the seller refuses to supply the other
buyers they are driven out of business
is this a sensible thing to do?
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
23
Vertical foreclosure 2
• Vertical foreclosure may reduce competition
– offsets benefits of removing double marginalization
• But for this to work
– foreclosure has to be a credible strategy for the merged firms
– foreclosure must be subgame perfect
• Consider two models of foreclosure
– Salinger (1988) with Cournot competition
– Ordover, Saloner and Salop (1990) with price competition
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
24
Vertical foreclosure 3
integrated
will
Suppose that there are some integratedThe
firms
and somefirm
independent
upstream and downstream producersnot source on the independent
market
Profit of an integrated firm is:
The integrated firm will
pI = (PD - cU - cD)qDi
not sell on the independent
market
Profit of an independent upstream firm is:
pU = (PU - cU)qUn
Profit of an independent downstream firm is:
pD = (PD - PU - cD)qDn
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
25
Vertical foreclosure 4
For the independent upstream firms to survive requires PU - cU > 0
The downstream unit of an integrated firm obtains input at cost cU
Buying from an independent firm costs PU > cU
so the downstream divisions will not source externally
Now suppose that an upstream division of an integrated firm is
selling to independent downstream firms it earns PU -But
cU on
each
unit sold
this
is true:
so
Profit from
diverting
output from
Divert one unitProfit
to its from
downstream
division: this leaves
the downstream
the external market
price unchanged: itselling
earns PD -selling
cU - cD on this unit diverted
internallyexternally
increases profits
PD - PU - cD > 0 for independent downstream firms to survive
PD - cU - cD > PU - cU requires: PD - PU - cD > 0
so the upstream divisions will not sell externally
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
26
Vertical foreclosure 5
• Foreclosure happens
– but is not necessarily harmful to consumers
• reduces number of buyers in the upstream market
• increases prices charged by independent sellers to non-integrated
downstream firms
• but integrated downstream divisions obtain inputs at cost
• puts pressure on non-integrated downstream firms
– provided there are “enough” independent upstream firms the anticompetitive effects of foreclosure will be offset by the cost
advantages of vertical integration
• There are also strategic effects that might prevent
foreclosure
– to avoid non-integrated firms from integrating
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
27
Vertical foreclosure 6
• The strategic aspects are considered in Ordover, Saloner
and Salop (OSS)
– suppose that there are two downstream and two upstream firms
• downstream firms make differentiated products
• upstream firms make homogeneous products
– both sets of firms compete in prices
– suppose that U1 merges with D1
•
•
•
•
suppose also that they credibly refuse to supply D2
then U2 is a monopoly supplier to D2
U2 and D2 set prices reflecting double marginalization
so they may well choose to merge also
– but U1 and D1 can foresee this and so may choose not to merge
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
28
Vertical foreclosure 7
• The OSS analysis thus far requires that there is no other source of the
input supply
– if there is such a source this will constrain U2’s price
• may make merger of U2 and D2 less likely
• Also, U1D1 may try to undermine the merger another way
– offer to supply D2 undercutting U2
– find a price such that U2 and D2 have no incentive to merge
– so complete foreclosure is avoided
• Note that there is a timing problem with this analysis
– U1 and D1 decide whether or not to merge
• if they do not the market continues as is
• if they do they seek to undermine a merger of U2 and D2
– but if U1 and D1 don’t merge U2 and D2 have a strong incentive to merge
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
29
Vertical Merger and Oligopoly
• The implication is that we should consider a simultaneous
model
– fear of vertical merger by one pair of firms might induce vertical
merger by other firms
– this might lead to a prisoners’ dilemma game
• vertical merger harms firms
• benefits consumers
• and is a Nash equilibrium for the merging firms
• Consider a (reasonably) simple model
– two upstream and two downstream Cournot firms
– downstream demand is P = A – BQ
– upstream firms’ marginal costs are cU and downstream firms’
marginal costs (excluding the upstream input) are cD
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
30
Vertical merger and oligopoly 2
• Competition in three stages
– stage 1:
• upstream and downstream firms choose simultaneously whether or
not to merge
– U1 merges with D1 and/or U2 with D2
– stage 2:
• non-merged upstream firms compete in quantities
• merged upstream firms supply their downstream divisions at marginal
cost cU
– stage 3:
• downstream firms compete in quantities
• Three cases:
– no vertical merger; one vertical merger; two vertical mergers
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
31
Vertical merger and oligopoly 3
• Case 1: no vertical merger
– competition in the upstream market generates an intermediate
product price PU
– so downstream marginal cost is PU + cD
– Cournot equilibrium output of each downstream firm is
• q1D = q2D = (A – PU – cD)/3B
– Cournot equilibrium profit of each downstream firm is
p1D = p2D = (A – PU – cD)2/9B
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
32
Vertical merger and oligopoly 4
• Aggregate output in the downstream market is derived
demand in the upstream market: QD = QU
– aggregate output is QD = QU = 2(A – PU – cD)/3B
– in inverse form PU = (A – cD) – 3BQU/2
– this is a standard linear demand p = a – bQ with a = (A – cD) and
b = 3B/2
– So Cournot equilibrium output of each upstream firm is
• q1U = q2U = [(A – cD) – cU]/(9B/2) = 2(A – cU – cD)/9B
– The equilibrium upstream input price is
• PU = (A – cD + 2cU)/3
– Profit of each upstream supplier is
p1U = p2U = 2(A – cU – cD)2/27B
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
33
Vertical merger and oligopoly 5
• Substitute for PU into the downstream equilibrium
– equilibrium downstream output is q1D = q2D = 2(A – cU – cD)/9B
– equilibrium profit is p1D = p2D = 4(A – cU – cD)2/81B
• As expected, output of each upstream firm equals output of
each downstream firm
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
34
Vertical merger and oligopoly 6
• Case 2: two vertical mergers
–
–
–
–
–
–
this is the simplest case
each downstream division has marginal cost cU + cD
and market demand is P = A – BQ
so Cournot equilibrium output downstream is
q1D = q2D = (A – cU – cD)/3B
and Cournot equilibrium profit of each downstream firm (and so of
each integrated firm) is
p1D = p2D = (A – cU – cD)2/9B
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
35
Vertical merger and oligopoly 7
• Case 3: One vertical merger
– suppose that U1 and D1 merge
– from the Salinger analysis the merged firm
• will not supply the non-merged downstream firm
• will not buy from the non-merged upstream firm
– suppose that U2 sets price PU for its intermediate product
•
•
•
•
•
•
downstream firm 2 has marginal cost PU + cD
downstream firm 1 has marginal cost cU + cD
downstream demand is P = A – BQ
so equilibrium Cournot outputs are
q1D = (A – 2cU – cD + PU)/3B
q2D = (A – 2PU – cD + cU)/3B
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
36
Vertical merger and oligopoly 8
• Equilibrium downstream profits are
p1D = (A – 2cU – cD + PU)2/9B
p2D = (A – 2PU – cD + cU)2/9B
– We know that PU > cU so the integrated downstream division has
greater output and profit than the non-integrated firm
– Output of the downstream non-merged firm is demand for the
upstream non-merged firm’s output: q2D = q2U
– so derived demand for the non-merged upstream firm is
•
•
•
•
PU = (A – cD + cU)/2 – 3Bq2U/2
this is linear of the form P = a – bq
and upstream firm 2 is a monopoly supplier with marginal cost cU
so sets output (a – cU)/2b and price (a + cU)/2
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
37
Vertical merger and oligopoly 9
– this gives the equilibrium upstream non-merged output:
• q2U = (A – cU – cD)/6B
– and price
• PU = (A + 3cU – cD)/4
– profit of the non-merged upstream firm is
p2D = (A – cU – cD)2/24B
– using the equilibrium non-merged input price PU we then have
• q1D = 5(A – cU – cD)/12B
• q2D = (A – cU – cD)/6B
– equilibrium downstream profits are
p1D = 25(A – cU – cD )2/144B
p2D = (A – cU – cD )2/36B
– The merged division is larger and more profitable than the nonmerged firm
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
38
Vertical merger and oligopoly 10
• We can now solve the first stage game
– calculate aggregate profits of an upstream and downstream firm or
an integrated firm
• merger will be suggested if it increases aggregate profit
–
–
–
–
note that all profits have the term (A – cU – cD)/B in common
so we can give this term any value
so assume that A = 100, B = 1 and cU = cD = 23
this gives the pay-off matrix:
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
39
Vertical merger and oligopoly 11
the perfect equilibrium is (Merger, Merger)
this is a prisoners’ dilemma game
Merger is dominant for both so timing is not important
Firms 1
No Merger
Merger
No Merger
Merger
$360, $360
$202.50, $506.25
$506.25, $202.50
$324, $324
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
40
Vertical merger - reappraisal
• Vertical merger has three effects in this model
– removes double marginalization
– reduces cost for a downstream integrated firm and makes
downstream market more competitive
– reduces competitive pressures in the upstream market
• In the model the first two effects dominate
– so consumers benefit from lower prices even with only one vertical
merger
– but in equilibrium the firms lose from vertical merger
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
41
Vertical merger – reappraisal 2
• Recall the proposed GE-Honeywell merger
– if this is the only merger then the merged firm gains and the nonmerged firms lose
• appears to be this that guided the EU Competition Directorate
• but consumers benefit even in this scenario
• and rivals have a clear strategic response: merge
– so the EU must have believed that merger by rivals was not
possible
• ever!
– and that if the integrated GE-Honeywell gains a monopoly position
price will rise
• but it is easy to check in the example that price would not rise
• So the decision remains questionable
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
42
Conglomerate Mergers
• Bring under common control firms whose products are
neither substitutes nor complements
– results in a diversified firm
– period from 1960s to early 1980s is when many were forms
• Is there a convincing rationale for this type of merger?
– if not then probably an accident of history
– gradually corrected by downsizing and focus on “core
competence”
• Possible rationales:
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
43
Conglomerate mergers 2
• Economies of scope
– but these generally derive from use of common inputs
– so merged firms should be related in some respect
• similar markets
• similar technologies
– data do not support this hypothesis
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
44
Conglomerate mergers 3
• Economize on transactions costs
– take a specialized machine can produce two goods A and B
• markets for A and B are concentrated
• if machine is used to produce only A there is spare capacity
– then owner may wish also to produce B – conglomeration
– the owner could also lease use of the machine to a specialized B
producer to avoid conglomeration
• but this has problems
– negotiating and bargaining over the lease
• conglomeration avoids these problems
– particularly important when the asset is knowledge intensive
– so this motive is reasonable
• but the assets are common to all the conglomerates products
• not supported by the data
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
45
Conglomerate mergers 4
• Managerial motives
– conglomeration suits interests of management but not shareholder
• division of ownership and control of large public corporations
• monitoring of management is far from perfect
• so management can pursue its own agenda to some extent
– suppose management compensation based on company growth
• easier to grow by acquisition than internally
• horizontal merger may be blocked by regulators
• so grow by conglomeration
– conglomeration to reduce management risk
• diversified firm has diversified risk
• this diversifies the risk that management faces
• Seems to be supported by the evidence
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
46
Chapter 17: Vertical and
Conglomerate Mergers
47