Transcript 投影片 1

• Chapter 16 Equilibrium
• Defer the discussion of the market supply
curve to later chapters and only denote it
by S(p): at any given price p, how many
units the suppliers are willing to supply.
• We have the market demand D(p) and the
market supply S(p). Basically the market
curve is the horizontal sum of the
individual curves. Now we can determine
the market equilibrium.
• Solve D(p*)=S(p*).
• Then at p* (taking price as given),
consumers choose the best they can
afford (utility maximization) and this
results the quantity demanded by all
consumers D(p*).
• Similarly, at p* (taking price as given),
producers choose the best they can
produce (profit maximization) and this
results the quantity supplied by all
suppliers S(p*).
• Furthermore, D(p*)=S(p*) implies that
market clears. So we have an equilibrium.
• The idea is, at the equilibrium price,
consumers max utilities, producers max
profits, and the market clears. The
equilibrium price is determined by all, yet
any individual is small so that when
making a choice, he takes the price as
given.
• When p< p*, typically D(p)>S(p), some
suppliers realize that they can sell at a
higher price to satisfy disappointed
consumers. This results a price increase
pressure.
• When p> p*, typically D(p)<S(p), some
suppliers are unable to sell and they try to
undercut the current price. This results a
price decrease pressure.
• The comparative statics is to see how the
equilibrium changes when the demand or
the supply changes.
• Look at an example: a quantity tax on a
good. A quantity tax is a tax levied per
unit of quantity bought or sold.
• As it suggests, either suppliers or
consumers are supposed to pay the tax t.
So whether the tax incidence (who gets to
pay and how much) will be the same in
the two cases?
• Consider the case where the supplier has
to pay. Suppose at p, before the tax,
suppliers supply x. After the tax, if the
suppliers supply x, the price must be p+t
since what matters is the price that the
suppliers can put into their pockets.
• Alternatively, suppose consumers have to
pay the price. Suppose at p, before the tax,
consumers consume x. After the tax, if
consumers still consume x, the price must
be p-t since what matters is the price that
the consumers have to take out of their
pockets.
• The two cases give you same results?
• We can also talk about the tax incidence a
bit. Imagine two extreme cases. One
where the supply is perfectly inelastic,
the other where it is perfectly elastic.
Suppose before the tax the equilibrium
price is p. In the former case, no way you
can get consumers to take more than p
out of pockets. So producers pay all the
tax. In the latter case, no way you can
make producers to take in less than p, so
consumers pay all the tax.
• These two extreme cases suggest that the
tax incidence has a lot to do with the
elasticities of demand and supply. When
it is more like the former, producers pay
most of the tax. When it is more like the
latter, consumers pay most of the tax.
• Can also talk about the welfare loss of a
tax. A quantity tax t makes the marginal
willingness to pay higher than the
marginal willingness to supply by t. So
for all units where MWP>MWS, there is
a deadweight loss (should be produced,
but are not produced).
• Alternatively, can calculates the change
of consumers’ surplus and producers’
surplus to reach the same conclusion.
• So why on earth is the market
equilibrium so efficient (Pareto efficient)?
Think about what Pareto efficiency
means. If MWPMWS, it is not efficient
because say if MWP>MWS, at least a
consumer and a producer can strike a
price inbetween to produce an additional
unit and the consumer is better off while
the producer is making more profit.
• It is clear that market equilibrium makes
MWP=MWS.
• What about looking at consumers only? If
MWP1>MWP2 (say 5>4), then consumer
1 can buy a unit of good in concern from
consumer 2 at the price of 4.5. This will
make both 1 and 2 better off.
• Market equilibrium achieves
MWP1=MWP2 because MWP1=p=MWP2.
• Look at producers only, if MWS1>MWS2
(say 5>4), then producer 2 can produce a
unit of good in concern more and this
increases 2’s cost by 4. Producer 1 can
reduce its production by a unit and this
decreases 1’s cost by 5. So in total, a cost
of 1 dollar is saved and this saved cost
(saved resource) can be used to produce.
• Market achieves MWS1=MWS2 because
MWS1=p=MWS2.