Transcript Slide 1
Chapter 10
Monopoly
10/1
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Monopoly
A
firm is a monopoly if no other
firm produces the same good or a
close substitute for it.
The degree to which goods are
substitutes is measured by the cross
price elasticity of demand.
10/2
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
The Monopolist’s Revenue Function
A
monopolist faces a downward sloping
market demand curve.
To sell additional units the monopolist
must lower its price. p=D(y).
Since all units must sell for the same
price, p=average revenue (AR).
Total revenue is output times price:
TR(y)=y(D)(y)
10/3
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
The Monopolist’s Revenue Function
Marginal
revenue MR(y) is the rate at
which total revenue changes with
changes in output.
Since the monopolist must reduce price
to sell additional units of output, for any
positive output, MR is less than price.
As Δp approaches zero, MR is equal to
(p) plus quantity (y) multiplied by the
slope of the demand curve.
10/4
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Figure 10.1 The monopolist’s marginal revenue
10/5
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Marginal Revenue and Price
Elasticity of Demand
Price
elasticity of demand (E) at a
point (y, p) on the demand curve is:
E=p/(y x slope of demand curve)
Rearranging: MR(y)=p(1-1/lEl)
Marginal revenue is positive if
demand is price elastic and is
negative if demand is price inelastic.
10/6
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Figure 10.2 A linear demand function and the
associated total and marginal revenue functions
10/7
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
From Figure 10.2
Linear
demand curve: P=a-by
TR=P*y, Therefore: TR(y)=ay-by2
MR(y)=a-2by
The demand curve intersects the
quantity axis at a/b.
The MR curve intersects the quantity
axis at a/2b.
10/8
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
From Figure 10.2
1.
2.
3.
10/9
When TR function has a positive
slope, MR is positive.
When the TR function is at its
maximum, MR is zero.
When TR function has a negative
slope slope, MR is negative.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Maximizing Profit
Maximize
profit by choosing output (y*)
where MC intersects MR (from below).
From the demand curve, find the price
(p*) that corresponds with the profit
maximizing y.
10/10
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Figure 10.3 Maximizing monopoly profit
10/11
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Figure 10.4 The inefficiency of monopoly
10/12
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
Because p* exceeds MC in equilibrium, some
potential gains from trade are not realized,
representing market failure.
Efficiency criterion requires producing output
to the point where p=MC. The monopoly
equilibrium is therefore not Pareto-optimal.
A deadweight loss occurs because at
equilibrium, there exists unrealized gains from
trade, signalling unrealized monopoly profit.
10/13
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Sources of Monopoly
Government
Franchise
Patent Monopoly
Resource Based Monopoly
Technological (Natural) Monopoly
Monopoly by Good Management
10/14
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Figure 10.5 Natural monopoly
10/15
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Regulatory Responses to a
Natural Monopoly
Average
Cost Pricing: Forcing the
monopoly to produce a level of
output where p=AC.
This regulation will fail to minimize
production costs.
10/16
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Figure 10.6 Average cost pricing
10/17
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Regulatory Responses to a
Natural Monopoly
Rate
of Return Regulation: Aimed
at limiting the rate of return on
invested capital.
Under this regulation, the firm will
choose an input bundle that is not
cost minimizing, choosing too much
capital and too little labour.
10/18
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Figure 10.7 Rate-of-return regulation
10/19
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Patent Policy
Appropriability
Problem: Many
inventions with social value are not
pursued because inventors do not
have the private incentives to pursue
them (they are not able to capture
the social benefits).
10/20
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Figure 10.8 The inducement to develop
10/21
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada
Optimal Patent Policy
At
the optimal patent period, the
marginal social benefit of increasing
the patent period is equal to the
marginal social cost.
The optimal patent policy maximizes
aggregate social value less
aggregate social costs.
10/22
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada