J Newhouse - Moral hazard-risk aversion tradeoff 0606
Download
Report
Transcript J Newhouse - Moral hazard-risk aversion tradeoff 0606
Reconsidering the Moral HazardRisk Aversion Tradeoff
Joseph P. Newhouse, © 2006
Many thanks to David Cutler, Richard Frank, Jon Gruber,
Tom McGuire, and Richard Zeckhauser for comments.
Some Prefatory Remarks
I thought about several topics for this talk
How and when does a subfield of economics
get established? When is it recognized by the
AEA classification system? When is there a
field journal? A professional society?
Clear that health economics is established; JHE
and HE now 1 and 2 in citation counts among
all economics and policy journals taken jointly!
The questions at the top were too hard
JHE and HE citation counts: Kodrzycki and Pingkang 2005, http://www.bos.frb.org/economic/wp/wp2005/wp0512.pdf.
The Future
Another natural topic: the future of the field
This is something of a fool’s errand, but
several factors suggest continued vitality:
Technological change and cost pressures
Use of administered pricing
Off-frontier production, e.g. variations
A second-best world; few unambiguous
predictions; need for empirical verification
Cost Sharing in Health Insurance
Instead of these topics I went back to what I
worked on at the beginning of my career;
the structure of cost sharing in health
insurance
For example, the size of a deductible
Although I assume a health insurance context,
the issues are also relevant in a health service
context
Outline of Talk
Received theory and empirics
The context for reconsidering
An elaboration of received theory
Incorporating time-inconsistent preferences
Received Theory
Cost sharing in health insurance is
traditionally framed as finding the optimal
tradeoff between moral hazard and risk
From Arrow (1963, 1968), Pauly (1968),
Zeckhauser (1970)
This is how our textbooks present it; e.g.,
Phelps, ch. 10, Feldstein, ch. 6, Zweifel and
Breyer, ch. 6
Arrow, AER, 1963, 53(5): 941-978; 1968, 58(3):537-539; Pauly, AER, 1968, 58(3):531-537; Zeckhauser, JET, 2(1):10-26.
Optimal Cost Sharing? - 1
Using the framework of trading off moral
hazard and risk, the RAND Health
Insurance Experiment calculated the
optimal cost sharing in 1983 dollars to be a
$200 individual deductible, followed by
25% coinsurance, to a $1,500 stop loss
Newhouse and the Insurance Experiment Group, Free for All?, chapter 4.
Optimal Cost Sharing? - 2
These values were slightly above those in
early 1980s indemnity policies, but….
The RAND calculations didn’t consider the
tax subsidy to employer paid premiums nor
liquidity constraints, which would have
lowered the optimal cost sharing
On the other hand, the calculations assumed
actuarily fair insurance
What Happened?
Instead of cost sharing escalating with
medical spending, we entered the era of
managed care with lower cost sharing
Lower cost sharing was consistent with the
idea that greater supply-side cost sharing
had altered the moral hazard-risk tradeoff,
which it probably did, but…
Two Problems Remained
Supply-side cost sharing was not well
placed to affect the decision to initiate
treatment for an episode, which the RAND
data suggested was the principal margin that
demand-side cost sharing affected, and…
Did Supply-Side Cost Sharing
Reduce Deadweight Loss?
With minimal demand-side cost sharing and
reliance on supply-side cost sharing there
was no mechanism to reveal willingness-topay, so that services a consumer would have
been willing to pay for might have been
denied
Did this play a role in the managed care
backlash?
Pauly and Ramsey, JHE, 1999, 18(4) 443-458; Rosenthal and Newhouse, Jnl Hlth Care Fin, 2002,28(4):1-10.
And Now…
Whether because of the backlash or because
supply-side cost sharing was about one-off
effects, or both, demand-side cost sharing is
now coming back on the table
The 2003 legislation authorizing Health
Savings Accounts prescribed a minimum
$1,050 deductible (individual), maximum
$5,250 stop-loss (2006 values)
HSAs and Optimal Cost Sharing
Despite product change, the HSA figures
are not so far from the RAND calculations
Health spending from 1983-2006 grew by ~5X
Ignoring the product change and using 5X to
inflate, the HSA deductible is in line
The stop loss is larger by 3.5X, but medical
care is a larger share of income, so a less than
proportional increase would be optimal
Law Says Preventive Services
Can Be Exempt
The Treasury defines preventive services as:
periodic health examinations; routine
prenatal and well-child care; tobacco
cessation programs; immunizations; weight
loss programs; various screening programs
Importantly for my story, the Treasury
excludes services that treat existing
conditions; they are subject to cost sharing
Should More Services be
Exempt?
In particular, should cost sharing be reduced
for chronic maintenance drugs and routine
maintenance visits for chronic conditions?
Considerable evidence that compliance
increases with less cost sharing
In some cases this may lower total lifetime cost;
in others it may not, but it may improve health
Evidence on Capped Drug
Benefits - 1
The following slides compare results from
two matched groups at Kaiser Northern
California
One group had a drug benefit capped at
$1,000 of member spending (no benefits
after that), and the other group had no cap
All were Medicare eligibles over 65 years of
age
Evidence on Capped Drug
Benefits - 2
The comparisons are for those who had
diabetes, hyperlipidemia, or hypertension,
and who filled a prescription for an antidiabetic drug, a lipid-lowering drug, or an
anti-hypertensive in the prior year
The tables show drug consumption, nonadherence, and physiologic outcomes
Adherence is having ≥ 80% of days covered
Diabetics
Benefit Not
Benefit
Odds Ratio
Capped (%) Capped (%) (95% C.I.)
Drug
Quantity ($)
--
--
Drug NonAdherence
21.2
26.2
Glycated
Hg > 8%
17.0
19.7
0.79
(0.73-0.86)
1.33
(1.18-1.48)
1.23
(1.03-1.46)
Odds ratio = capped/non-capped; Source: Hsu, et al., NEJM, June 1, 2006
Odds Ratio results control for age, sex, race, comorbidities, office, ED copays. Physiologic odds ratio controls for initial value.
High Cholesterol
Benefit Not
Benefit
Odds Ratio
Capped (%) Capped (%) (95% C.I.)
Drug
Quantity ($)
--
--
Drug NonAdherence
26.5
31.4
LDL>130
mg/dl
19.6
21.3
0.73
(0.70-0.77)
1.27
(1.19-1.34)
1.13
(1.03-1.25)
Odds ratio = capped/non-capped; Source: Hsu, et al., NEJM, June 1, 2006
Odds Ratio results control for age, sex, race, comorbidities, office, ED copays. Physiologic odds ratio controls for initial value.
Hypertensives
Benefit Not
Benefit
Odds Ratio
Capped (%) Capped (%) (95% C.I.)
Drug
Quantity ($)
--
--
Drug NonAdherence
14.6
18.1
SBP>140
mm Hg
38.5
39.5
0.85
(0.82-0.89)
1.30
(1.23-1.38)
1.05
(1.00-1.09)
Odds ratio = capped/non-capped; Source: Hsu, et al., NEJM, June 1, 2006
Odds Ratio results control for age, sex, race, comorbidities, office, ED copays. Physiologic odds ratio controls for initial value.
Use and Costs, Rate/100
Benefit Not
Capped
Benefit
Capped
Odds Ratio
(95% C.I.)
ED Visits
45.2
49.2
Nonelective
Admissions
Total Cost
16.6
18.7
1.09
(1.04-1.14)
1.13
(1.05-1.21)
--
--
0.99
(0.94-1.04)
Odds Ratio results control for age, sex, race, years of Kaiser membership, comorbidities, office, ED copays.
Conclusion from Kaiser Study
A drug benefit capped at $1,000 versus no
cap led to less compliance with chronic
disease regimens, poorer physiologic health,
and cost increases in other medical services
that about equaled the savings in drug costs
If non-compliance were to continue and
physiologic health to deteriorate further, the
future increase in other medical spending may
exceed the decrease in drug spending
Additional Evidence - 1
Soumerai, et al. studies on caps in two
Medicaid populations: 3 drug/month limit
saved 35% on drugs, but more than doubled
nursing home admissions
Among schizophrenics: Cap on mental health
drugs raised other spending by 17 times the
savings on drugs
Soumerai, et al., NEJM, 1991, 325:1072-1077, 1994, 331:650-655.
Are You Saying: So What?
Did you already know that initial benefits
with caps were poor economics and policy?
Then ask yourself whether an actuarily
equivalent deductible with full coverage
over the deductible would have yielded
better or worse compliance results?
How many think better results?
Additional Evidence - 2
In any event, if you don’t like caps, there
are analogous findings about drug copays
Huskamp, et al. and Goldman, et al. find
that increased copays decreased the use of
ACE inhibitors, anti-hypertensives, antidiabetics, and statins, though they have no
data on other medical costs
Huskamp et al, NEJM, 2003, 349:2224-2232; Goldman, et al., JAMA, 2004, 291:2344-2350.
Additional Evidence – 3
Tamblyn, et al. find imposing cost sharing
for drugs among the poor and the elderly in
Quebec reduced drug use by 15-22%, but
led to an approximate doubling of serious
adverse events, meaning death,
hospitalization, or nursing home admission
No cost data, but it seems likely that total costs
increased
Tamblyn, et al., JAMA, 2001, 285(4):421-429.
Additional Evidence - 4
Rosen, et al. (2005) simulate that full
coverage of ACE inhibitors for Medicare
beneficiaries who are diabetic would
increase QALYs and save money relative to
the default cost sharing in Part D
Rosen, et al., Annals of Internal Med, 2005, 143(2):89-99.
An Extreme Example
With Directly Observed Therapy,
tuberculosis patients are paid to be observed
swallowing their medications
Negative cost sharing!
3 Cases to Stretch the Usual
Risk-Moral Hazard Tradeoff
An easy one to warm up
A second one that is a straightforward
elaboration of received theory
A third one that ventures further afield,
time-inconsistent preferences
An Easy Case
The marginal social cost of another pill is
frequently negligible, so any induced
consumption has negligible deadweight loss
Assuming no increase in costs elsewhere,
no moral hazard-risk aversion tradeoff
I assume for the remainder of the talk that
marginal social cost is non-negligible
Of course, private costs of the pill are positive
Before Coming to Case 2: How Is
Cost Sharing Determined?
For many cost sharing is determined by
employer or government choice
Even with choice among plans, employer may
have standardized cost sharing
As a result:
In many cases cost sharing is exogenous
And even with choice of plan, a person’s health
costs are shared with an insurance pool
The Employer’s Choice
How does an employer choose cost sharing?
Goldstein-Pauly (1976): Employers minimize
labor cost, look at benefit to marginal worker;
unions look at benefit to median worker
–
Labor cost = health care cost + productivity effects
Miller (2005): Employer who minimizes cost
and offers plan choice sells more generous plan
as an upgrade; a lump sum subsidy to all plans
is probably not optimal
Goldstein-Pauly, in Role of Health Insurance in the Health Services Sector, 1976; Miller, JHE,24(5):931-939.
Public Insurance
Straightforward extension of Goldstein-
Pauly median employee model to median
voter?
An Implication
Tenure in the employment group is relevant
for a cost-minimizing employer; ceteris
paribus, firms with longer job tenure will
provide insurance with less cost sharing if
those services reduce future costs
I have not tested this
In Medicare life cycle costs relevant
A Note on Measuring the RiskMoral Hazard Tradeoff
Much empirical analysis, the RAND HIE
included, uses an annual time frame, but
lifetime risk is relevant with chronic disease
Positive intertemporal correlation of health
spending from chronic disease raises risk
for a given level of positive cost sharing
Second Case: An Elaboration of
Received Theory
Because costs are shared within a common
insurance pool, less cost sharing for those
services and/or individuals that lowers
overall spending for the pool is the usual
case of a subsidy to recognize an externality
Here too no moral hazard-risk aversion tradeoff
Held-Pauly (1990) take up an analogous case,
but don’t frame the issue as optimal cost
sharing for all services
Held and Pauly, JHE, 1990, 9(4): 447-461.
A Third Case: Take Your
Medicine!
We surely all heard that from our mothers
So why as adults do some persons not take
drugs that will improve their future health
but may not save them money?
One Answer
They are insured for other medical services
and place a low value on the uninsured
health costs such as pain, suffering
The second part doesn’t seem very plausible
for the above cases of chronic disease
Models of time-inconsistent behavior seem
relevant in this context
Models of Time-Consistent and
Time-Inconsistence Preferences
Assume a standard health economics utility function:
Ut U ( xt , Ht (m, x))
With time-consistent preferences (standard discounting), or:
T t
i
Ut i
0<<1
i 0
Time-inconsistent preferences, quasi-hyperbolic discounting:
T t
Ut Ut i
i
i 1
0 < β, < 1
Maximize lifetime utility s.t. lifetime budget constraint
Strotz, 1956; Akerlof, 1991; Laibson, 1997; O'Donoghue and Rabin, 1999; Frederick, Loewenstein, and O'Donoghue, 2002.
Already a Health Application
Gruber-Koszegi (2001, 2004) use a model
with time-inconsistent preferences to justify
much higher cigarette taxes to induce
“compliance” with not smoking
With this model cigarette taxes are less
regressive than usually assumed and may be
progressive because “internalities”
disproportionately accrue to the low income
Gruber-Koszegi, QJE, 2001, 116(4), 1261-1305; J Pub Econ, 2004,88(9-10): 1959-1987.
Time-Inconsistent Preferences
and Optimal Cost Sharing - 1
Solutions in these models depend on
whether the individual is aware of the timeinconsistent preferences or not
Solutions are easier if unaware (naïve case)
Also can depend on whether example is
immediate reward or immediate cost
Chronic disease application is immediate cost;
small difference between and β can generate
large welfare losses if individual is naïve
Laibson, QJE, 1997, 112(2):443-477; O'Donoghue and Rabin, AER, 1999,89(1):103-124. .
Time-Inconsistent Preferences
and Optimal Cost Sharing - 2
In other words, with time-inconsistent
preferences, induced compliance can be
welfare increasing, potentially by a large
amount, independent of risk
Specific Subsidies
Very specific cost sharing structures such as
free ACE inhibitors for elderly diabetics are
not found in the market (selection), but
disease management and case management
use non-price methods toward similar ends
Medicare could adopt such a structure and there
could be mandates in private insurance
Conclusions: Social Perspective
Current cost sharing structure may not be
optimal from society’s perspective
Without considering risk, welfare may be
improved by selectively lowering cost
sharing for certain persons and/or certain
services
Case 1: Negligible marginal social cost
From social perspective, negligible cost sharing
Social Perspective, cont.
Case 2: Induced greater compliance that
adds cost for the specific good or service
but saves overall lifetime costs
Additional subsidy; externality
Case 3:Induced greater compliance that
increases value of health by more than cost
Models of time-inconsistent behavior relevant?
Marginal Benefit of health = MC compliance
Conclusions: Private Perspective
From a private perspective:
Case 1 of negligible cost probably doesn’t exist
Cases 2, 3: Optimal subsidy will generally be
less than from social perspective
Conclusions: Policy and
Research
HSA legislation seems too restrictive
More generally, current cost sharing
structure seems sub-optimal, even from a
private perspective
Optimal cost sharing seems like a fruitful
field for future research