Trade policy analysis: choosing the appropriate methodology
Download
Report
Transcript Trade policy analysis: choosing the appropriate methodology
Trade policy analysis: choosing
the appropriate methodology
Marc Bacchetta
ERSD/WTO
Outline
Research based policy making
Criteria for choosing a methodology
Key methodologies
– Modelling assumptions
– Required resources
Research based policy making
Research based information on policies is
needed at different stages of the policy
making process
– Proposal
– Policy dialogue with stakeholders
– Implementation
Dialogue
Dialogue between researchers and policy
stakeholders is crucial
Researchers may help policy makers
specify questions
Researchers should guide the choice of
appropriate methodologies
Methodology: the question
Which
approach is best suited to
answer the question at stake given
existing constraints ?
Choice of methodology is not
necessarily straightforward
The question should dictate the choice of a
methodology ...
But there are various constraints:
– Time and resources
– Sunk costs (incl. familiarity with certain
methodologies, institutional constraints)
– Fashion
Key approaches
Descriptive statistics
Modelling approaches:
– Ex ante vs ex post approaches
– Econometric vs simulation models
– Partial vs general equilibrium
Ex ante vs ex post approaches
Ex ante simulation involves projecting the effects
of a policy change on a set of economic variables
of interest
– Can answer “what if” questions
Ex post approaches use historical data to conduct
an analysis of the effects of past trade policy
– Can answer “what if” questions if estimated
parameters are used for simulation (which assumes
that past relations continue to be relevant)
Econometric vs simulation models
In econometric models, parameter values are
estimated using statistical techniques
– Parameter values come with confidence intervals
– Parameter estimation is resource intensive
– Results are specific to one country or group of
countries
In simulation models, parameters are typically
drawn from a variety of sources and some are
calibrated
Descriptive statistics (1)
Trade flows analysis
Example: assessment of trade patterns
and/or trade performance
Conceptual tools
– Revealed comparative advantage, intraindustry trade, export diversification, etc.
Empirical tools
– Entropy indices, revealed comparative adv.
Trade performance and
competitiveness assessment
Trade in services
Merchandise trade
– Trade performance
Growth and pattern in the direction of trade
Composition of trade
Export concentration and principal products
– Competitiveness, specialization and complementarity
International competitiveness of exports
Export specialization
Trade complementarity and intensity
...
Indices
Export specialization
index
Trade
complementarity
index
ESI ijk
X ijk X ijt
M jk M jt
TCIij RCAik RCD jk M wk M w
k
– with
X ik X i
RCAik
M wk M w
RCD jk
M jk M j
M wk M w
Descriptive statistics (2)
Trade policy analysis
Example: trade policy assessment
Conceptual tools
– Effective protection, non tariff barriers, bound
and applied tariffs, tariff escalation, etc.
Empirical tools
– Averages, dispersion indices, coverage ratios,
etc.
Trade policy assessments
Trade policy reviews
– Trade and investment regime
– Trade policies by measure and by sector
Tariff profiles
NAMA tariff simulations
Econometric estimation of gravity
equations
Can be used to study the impact of trade
policy variables on trade flows
Example: effect of regional trade
agreement
Ex post: not well suited for making
predictions
No welfare effects
Econometric estimation of gravity
equations
Reasonable data requirements
Reasonable entry costs
Cost of econometric software package ?
Importance of integrating theory with
estimation
Econometric estimation of economic
consequences of trade
Example: assessment of the distributional
effects of trade policy
Ex post
Variable level of econometric
sophistication
Variable data requirements
Partial equilibrium simulations
Focuses on a specific market or product
and ignores interactions with other markets
Best suited for the analysis of sectoral
policies, or when interactions with other
markets are expected to be limited
Allows to include more market relevant
details than GE models
Ex: assessing the welfare effect of a
reduction of the tariff on wheat
Partial equilibrium simulations
A number of partial equilibrium models
have been developed to simulate
international trade policy changes
– Those include SMART, ATPSM, SWOPSIM
Data requirements are manageable
– Elasticities are crucial
General equilibrium simulations
GE explicitly accounts for all the links between
sectors of an economy – households, firms,
governments and the rest of the world
Imposes constraints s.t. income equals
expenditure
Trade off between detail and breadth of coverage
Assesses effects of policy changes on aggregate
and sectoral variables, including:
– Income, production, employment, relative factor and
product prices, etc.
General equilibrium simulations
Single or multiple country models
Highly intensive in data and parameters
– SAM, behavioural parameters, elasticities
– GTAP provides data and a simple model
Entry cost is significant
High risk of misinterpretation
Paper on Turkey
Glenn Harrison, Thomas Rutherford and David Tarr
(2003) “Trade Liberalization, poverty and Efficient
Equity,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 71 (1),
June 2003, 97-128.
Policy application—joining a Customs Union with the
European Union (not membership).
Small Open Economy model with 40 households, 20
rural and 20 urban.
Economic Theory suggests that for developing countries
trade liberalization should shift production toward labor
intensive products. That should be pro-poor.
In Turkey the authors did not find this. They estimated
that the poor lost. Why?
They show that estimation of factor intensities is crucial
to a sensible link between trade policy and poverty
analysis.
Input-Output tables notoriously fail to accurately report
factor intensities. Capital’s share is a residual. In
Agriculture, labor’s earnings are underreported, so it is
the most capital intensive sector in IO tables. Services
sectors are also problematical.
In Turkey locomotives are reported as 100% labor;
textiles are capital intensive.
Perverse results may be obtained if estimates are based
on IO table factor intensities. The lesson learned for
future applications is that factor intensities should be
estimated outside of the input-output model.
The authors caution consumers of these models to ask
producers how they have obtained the values of their
factor intensities.
The study identifies sectors where an increase in the tariff
rates will increase the welfare of the poor. The authors
caution, however, that political economy reasons suggest
that these models should not be used for industrial policy
to help the poor. Likely to be abused like the many other
arguments to depart from tariff uniformity.
Partial vs general equilibrium models
Capturing economy wide linkages
Consistency wrt budget constraints
Capturing disaggregated effects
Capturing complicated policy mechanisms
Use of timely data
Capturing short and med. term effects
Capturing long term effects
Past performance in projecting impacts
CGE PE
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
Conflicting results
Policy makers don’t like conflicting results
In most cases different results reflect
different assumptions
Such differences are difficult to avoid
What matters is the presentation of the
results
References
Piermartini, R. and R. Teh (2005)
Demystifying modelling methods for trade
policy, WTO Discussion Paper No. 10
Bowen, H.P., A. Hollander and J.-M.
Viaene (1998) Applied international trade
analysis, University of Michigan Press
Abler, D. (2006) Approaches to measuring
the effects of trade agreements, CATPRN
Paper 2006-1