Transcript Slide 1

Comments by
John Hassler
IIES, Stockholm University
Sailing to Gotland
Västervik
Visby
Sailing to Gotland
?
Fårö
Västervik
Prudent Navigation
Fårö
Västervik
Prudent budget planning
•
Does this apply to government budget planning?
•
Most likely does uncertainty increase expected marginal cost of taxation.
•
Concerns about future uncertainty should be;
– Larger the higher expected future taxes are.
– Lower the better the financial position of the government is.
•
Leads to recommendation of more positive expected surplus than otherwise
and a build up of government financial assets. Very similar to the case of an
individual who accumulates a buffer stock of savings.
•
BUT;
– This has nothing to do with ”deliberate underestimation of income”, ”exaggeration
of costs” and ”pessimism”.
– Perfectly in line with Barro’s smoothing of tax distortions, marginal cost of
taxation today set equal to expected future marginal costs of taxation.
Prudent budget planning
- Costs of government buffers
•
Theoretical argument for debt; debt is good since it can be used by
households to build buffer stocks against idiosyncratic shocks.
– Probably not relevant for small open economy where individuals have acces to
world capital markets.
•
Surplus/deficits is one way to transfer taxation and spending over time.
Considering long periods also between generations.
•
How much – how costly is it?
•
Requires elaborate model and value judgments to answer.
•
Here, some back-of-the-envelope calculations on the size of buffer stocks
and intergenerational transfers.
Simple numerical example
• First two things to note:
– A reduction in surplus leads to less government assets in future
requiring increasing taxes or falling spending,
– Government assets as a share of GPD will not explode if surplus
is positive for ever. Long run expected debt is:
surplus rate
d
GDP growth rate inflationrate
•
Intuition -- need a surplus to compensate for erosion by inflation and
to keep up with growing GDP.
•
Suppose also that expected inflation and growth both are 2% and the
real bond yields is 1%.
Compare 0,1 and 2% targeted financial surplus.
•
Net government assets
Share of GDP
2% surplus
0.5
0.4
0.3
1% surplus
0.2
Buffer stock slowly approaches 50%
of GDP if financial surplus is 2%.
Half of adjustment in about 25 years.
0.1
0 surplus
0
20
40
60
Years from now
80
100
Taxes with constant surplus
0.50
2% surplus
0.49
1% surplus
0 surplus
0.48
0.47
Initial difference in taxes/spendings
of 2% erodes over time to 0.5%.
0.46
0.45 0
20
40
x
60
Years from now
80
100
Intergenerational transfers
• A 2% surplus leads to asset build-up and thus an expected transfer
to future generations. How much?
• A simplistic example:
– Suppose one generation is 30 years.
– Suppose the benefits of tax reduction would go to current old
generation, paid by future ones.
– Over 30 years 2% surplus leads to a build up of assets  30% of GDP
relative to case of zero surplus.
– This is about 1% of GDP during this period.
Conclusion
•
2% surplus rather than 0 leads to net govt. assets of 50% of GDP.
•
Awaiting more serious quantitative work, this dos not seem unreasonable
from a prudent point of view.
•
Rational prudence better than over-pessimism (more transparency and
accountability)
•
A little more than half is generated in one generation leading to a fairly small
intergenerational transfer.
•
Have not discussed:
– Political failures – is the money going to burn in the pockets of the politicians?
– Other reasons for larger intergenerational transfers.
– Portfolio choice, risk management, state dependent taxes.