FA09 cs188 lecture 1..

Download Report

Transcript FA09 cs188 lecture 1..

CS 188: Artificial Intelligence
Fall 2009
Lecture 17: Bayes Nets IV
10/27/2009
Dan Klein – UC Berkeley
Announcements
 Midterms
 In glookup, back at end of lecture
 Class did really well!
 Assignments
 W3 out later this week
 P4 out next week
 Contest!
2
Approximate Inference
3
Approximate Inference
 Simulation has a name: sampling
F
 Sampling is a hot topic in machine learning,
and it’s really simple
S
 Basic idea:
 Draw N samples from a sampling distribution S
 Compute an approximate posterior probability
 Show this converges to the true probability P
A
 Why sample?
 Learning: get samples from a distribution you don’t know
 Inference: getting a sample is faster than computing the right
answer (e.g. with variable elimination)
4
Prior Sampling
+c
-c
0.5
0.5
Cloudy
+c
-c
+s
+s
-s
+s
-s
0.1
0.9
0.5
0.5
+r
-r
-s
+r
-r
+c
Sprinkler
+w
-w
+w
-w
+w
-w
+w
-w
0.99
0.01
0.90
0.10
0.90
0.10
0.01
0.99
Rain
WetGrass
-c
+r
-r
+r
-r
0.8
0.2
0.2
0.8
Samples:
+c, -s, +r, +w
-c, +s, -r, +w
…
5
Prior Sampling
 This process generates samples with probability:
…i.e. the BN’s joint probability
 Let the number of samples of an event be
 Then
 I.e., the sampling procedure is consistent
6
Example
 We’ll get a bunch of samples from the BN:
+c, -s, +r, +w
+c, +s, +r, +w
-c, +s, +r, -w
+c, -s, +r, +w
-c, -s, -r, +w
Cloudy
C
Sprinkler
S
Rain
R
WetGrass
W
 If we want to know P(W)






We have counts <+w:4, -w:1>
Normalize to get P(W) = <+w:0.8, -w:0.2>
This will get closer to the true distribution with more samples
Can estimate anything else, too
What about P(C| +w)? P(C| +r, +w)? P(C| -r, -w)?
Fast: can use fewer samples if less time (what’s the drawback?)
7
Rejection Sampling
 Let’s say we want P(C)
 No point keeping all samples around
 Just tally counts of C as we go
Cloudy
C
Sprinkler
S
Rain
R
WetGrass
W
 Let’s say we want P(C| +s)
 Same thing: tally C outcomes, but
ignore (reject) samples which don’t
have S=+s
 This is called rejection sampling
 It is also consistent for conditional
probabilities (i.e., correct in the limit)
+c, -s, +r, +w
+c, +s, +r, +w
-c, +s, +r, -w
+c, -s, +r, +w
-c, -s, -r, +w
8
Sampling Example
 There are 2 cups.
 The first contains 1 penny and 1 quarter
 The second contains 2 quarters
 Say I pick a cup uniformly at random, then pick a
coin randomly from that cup. It's a quarter (yes!).
What is the probability that the other coin in that
cup is also a quarter?
Likelihood Weighting
 Problem with rejection sampling:
 If evidence is unlikely, you reject a lot of samples
 You don’t exploit your evidence as you sample
 Consider P(B|+a)
Burglary
Alarm
-b, -a
-b, -a
-b, -a
-b, -a
+b, +a
 Idea: fix evidence variables and sample the rest
Burglary
Alarm
-b +a
-b, +a
-b, +a
-b, +a
+b, +a
 Problem: sample distribution not consistent!
 Solution: weight by probability of evidence given parents
10
Likelihood Weighting
+c
-c
0.5
0.5
Cloudy
+c
-c
+s
+s
-s
+s
-s
0.1
0.9
0.5
0.5
+r
-r
-s
+r
-r
+c
Sprinkler
+w
-w
+w
-w
+w
-w
+w
-w
0.99
0.01
0.90
0.10
0.90
0.10
0.01
0.99
Rain
WetGrass
-c
+r
-r
+r
-r
0.8
0.2
0.2
0.8
Samples:
+c, +s, +r, +w
…
11
Likelihood Weighting
 Sampling distribution if z sampled and e fixed evidence
Cloudy
C
 Now, samples have weights
S
R
W
 Together, weighted sampling distribution is consistent
12
Likelihood Weighting
 Likelihood weighting is good
 We have taken evidence into account as
we generate the sample
 E.g. here, W’s value will get picked
based on the evidence values of S, R
 More of our samples will reflect the state
of the world suggested by the evidence
 Likelihood weighting doesn’t solve
all our problems
Cloudy
C
S
Rain
R
W
 Evidence influences the choice of
downstream variables, but not upstream
ones (C isn’t more likely to get a value
matching the evidence)
 We would like to consider evidence
when we sample every variable
13
Markov Chain Monte Carlo*
 Idea: instead of sampling from scratch, create samples
that are each like the last one.
 Procedure: resample one variable at a time, conditioned
on all the rest, but keep evidence fixed. E.g., for P(b|c):
+b
+a
+c
-b
+a
+c
-b
-a
+c
 Properties: Now samples are not independent (in fact
they’re nearly identical), but sample averages are still
consistent estimators!
 What’s the point: both upstream and downstream
variables condition on evidence.
14
Decision Networks
 MEU: choose the action which
maximizes the expected utility
given the evidence
Umbrella
U
 Can directly operationalize this
with decision networks
 Bayes nets with nodes for
utility and actions
 Lets us calculate the expected
utility for each action
Weather
 New node types:
 Chance nodes (just like BNs)
 Actions (rectangles, cannot
have parents, act as observed
evidence)
 Utility node (diamond, depends
on action and chance nodes)
Forecast
[DEMO: Ghostbusters]
16
Decision Networks
 Action selection:
 Instantiate all
evidence
 Set action node(s)
each possible way
 Calculate posterior
for all parents of
utility node, given
the evidence
 Calculate expected
utility for each action
 Choose maximizing
action
Umbrella
U
Weather
Forecast
17
Example: Decision Networks
Umbrella = leave
Umbrella
U
Weather
Umbrella = take
A
W
P(W)
leave
sun
100
sun
0.7
leave
rain
0
rain
0.3
take
sun
20
take
rain
70
W
Optimal decision = leave
U(A,W)
Evidence in Decision Networks
 Find P(W|F=bad)
Umbrella
 Select for evidence
W
U
P(W)
W
P(W)
W
P(F=bad|W)
sun
0.7
sun
0.7
sun
0.2
rain
0.3
rain
0.3
rain
0.9
F
P(F|sun)
good
0.8
bad
0.2
F
Weather
 First we join P(W) and
P(bad|W)
 Then we normalize
P(F|rain)
good
0.1
bad
0.9
Forecast
W
P(W,F=bad)
W
P(W | F=bad)
sun
0.14
sun
0.34
rain
0.27
rain
0.66
Example: Decision Networks
Umbrella = leave
Umbrella
W
P(W|F=bad)
sun
0.34
rain
0.66
U
Umbrella = take
Optimal decision = take
Weather
Forecast
=bad
A
W
U(A,W)
leave
sun
100
leave
rain
0
take
sun
20
take
rain
70
[Demo]
20
Conditioning on Action Nodes
 An action node can be a
parent of a chance node
S
A
S’
U
T(s,a,s’)
R(s,a,s’)
 Chance node conditions on
the outcome of the action
 Action nodes are like
observed variables in a
Bayes’ net, except we max
over their values
21
Value of Information
 Idea: compute value of acquiring evidence
 Can be done directly from decision network
 Example: buying oil drilling rights




Two blocks A and B, exactly one has oil, worth k
Prior probabilities 0.5 each, & mutually exclusive
Drilling in either A or B has MEU = k/2
Fair price of drilling rights: k/2
 Question: what’s the value of information







Value of knowing which of A or B has oil
Value is expected gain in MEU from new info
Survey may say “oil in a” or “oil in b,” prob 0.5 each
If we know OilLoc, MEU is k (either way)
Gain in MEU from knowing OilLoc?
VPI(OilLoc) = k/2
Fair price of information: k/2
DrillLoc
U
OilLoc
O
P
D
O
U
a
1/2
a
a
k
b
1/2
a
b
0
b
a
0
b
b
k
22
Value of Perfect Information

Current evidence E=e, utility depends on S=s

Potential new evidence E’: suppose we knew E’ = e’

BUT E’ is a random variable whose value is currently unknown, so:
 Must compute expected gain over all possible values

(VPI = value of perfect information)
23
VPI Example: Weather
MEU with no evidence
Umbrella
U
MEU if forecast is bad
Weather
MEU if forecast is good
Forecast
Forecast distribution
F
P(F)
good
0.59
bad
0.41
A
W
U
leave
sun
100
leave
rain
0
take
sun
20
take
rain
70
7.8
24
VPI Properties
 Nonnegative in expectation
 Nonadditive ---consider, e.g., obtaining Ej twice
 Order-independent
27
Quick VPI Questions
 The soup of the day is either clam chowder or split pea,
but you wouldn’t order either one. What’s the value of
knowing which it is?
 If you have $10 to bet and odds are 3 to 1 that Berkeley
will beat Stanford, what’s the value of knowing the
outcome in advance, assuming you can make a fair bet
for either Cal or Stanford?
 What if you are morally obligated not to bet against Cal,
but you can refrain from betting?
28