Norm and Derivatives
Download
Report
Transcript Norm and Derivatives
Theory of Differentiation in
Statistics
Mohammed Nasser
Department of Statistics
1
Relation between Statistics and
Differentiation
Statistical
Concepts/Techniques
Use of Differentiation
Theory
Study of shapes of univariate An easy application of firstpdfs
order and second-order
derivatives
Calculation/stablization of
An application of Taylor’s
variance of a random variable theorem
Calculation of Moments from
MGF/CF
Differentiating MGF/CF
2
Relation between Statistics and
Differentiation
Description of a density/ a
model
Optimize some risk
functional/regularized
functional/ empirical risk
functional with/without
constraints
Influence function to assess
robustness of a statistical
dy/dx=k, dy/dx=kx
Needs heavy tools of
nonlinear optimization
Techniques that depend on
multivariate differential
calculus and functional
differential calculus
An easy application of
directional derivative in
function space
3
Relation between Statistics and
Differentiation
Classical delta theorem to
find asymptotic distribution
Von Mises Calculus
Relation between probability
measures and probability
density functions
An application of ordinary
Taylor’s theorem
Extensive application of
functional differential
calculus
Radon Nikodym theorem
4
Monotone Function
f(x)
Monotone
Decreasing
Monotone
Increasing
Strictly
Increasing
Non
Decreasing
Strictly
Decreasing
Non
Increasing
5
Increasing/Decreasing test
f : R
R
f ( x ) x 3
f : R R
f ( x ) x 3
6
Example of Monotone Increasing Function
0
f : R
R
f ( x ) x 3
7
Maximum/Minimum
a
b
Is there any sufficient condition that
guarantees existence of global
max/global min/both?
8
Some Results to Mention
If the function is continuous and its domain is compact,
the function attains its extremum
It’s a very general result It holds for any compact
space other compact set of Rn.
Any convex ( concave) function attains its global min (
max).
Without satisfying any of the above conditions some
functions may have global min ( max).
Firstly, proof of
existence of
Then
Calculation of
extremum
9
What Does" f I ( x0 ) 0" Say about f
Fermat’s Theorem: if f has local maximum or minimum
at c, and if f I (c) exist, then f I (c) 0, but converse is not
true
10
Concavity
II
•If f ( x) 0 for all x in (a,b), then the graph of f concave on (a,b).
•If f II ( x) 0 for all x in (a,b), then the graph of f concave on (a,b).
•If f II (c) 0 then f has a point of inflection at c.
c
Point of inflection
11
Maximum/Minimum
Let f(x) be a differential function on an interval I
•f is maximum at c I if f I (c) 0 and f II (c) 0
•f is maximum at c I if f (c) 0 and f (c) 0
I
II
•If f I ( x) 0 for all x in an interval, then f is maximum at first
end point of the interval if left side is closed and
minimum at last end point if right side is closed.
I
f
•If ( x) 0 for
all x in an interval, then f is minimum at first
end point of the interval if left side is closed and
maximum at last end point if right side is closed.
12
Normal Distribution
The probability density function is given as,
f ( x)
1
e
2
1 x
2
2
lt f (x ) 0
x
continuous on R
f(x)>=0
Differentiable on
R
Convex
Concave
Convex
13
Normal Distribution
Now,
1
f ( x)
e
2
1 x
2
2
1 1 x
log f log
2 2
1 I
x 1
f 0
f
1 x
I
f
f 0
x
2
Take log both side
Put first derivative
equal to zero
14
Normal Distribution
f
II
1
2
1
2
1
2
( x ) f
I
f
f
I
f
Sincex
f 0
Therefore f is maximum at x
15
Normal Distribution
Put 2nd derivative equal to zero
f
II
0
1
2
( x ) f
I
f 0
x
f f 0
2
x
( x )2
2
1 0
2 0
{x ( )}{x ( )} 0
x
Therefore f has point of inflection at
x
16
Logistic Distribution
The distribution function is defined as,
ex
F ( x)
; x
x
1 e
Convex
Concave
17
Logistic Distribution
Take first derivative with respect to x
ex
F ( x)
0; x
x 2
(1 e )
I
Therefore F is strictly increasing
Take2nd derivative and put equal to zero
x
x
e
(
1
e
)
F II ( x )
0
x 3
(1 e )
e x ( 1 e x ) 0
ex 1
x log(1) 0
x 0
Therefore F has a point of inflection at x=0
18
Logistic Distribution
Now we comment that F has no maximum and
minimum.
Since,
F II ( x) 0; x ( ,0)
F II ( x) 0; x (0, )
Therefore F is convex on ( ,0) and concave on (0, ).
19
Variance of a Function of Poisson Variate
Using Taylor’s Theorem
We know that,
Mean , E (Y ) , V ariance,V (Y )
We are interested to find the Variance of g (Y ) Y
V ( Y ) ?
Given that ,
1
1
g(Y ) Y g I (Y ) Y 2
2
1
2
1
1 1
I
I
2
g ()
g ( )
2
4
20
Variance of a Function of Poisson Variate
Using Taylor’s Theorem
The Taylor’s series is defined as,
g (Y ) g ( ) g I ( )(Y ) o( Y )
g (Y ) g ( ) g I ( )(Y )
V ( g (Y )) 0 g ( ) V (Y )
1 1
V (Y )
4
1
4
Therefore the variance of
1
Y is
4
I
2
21
Risk Functional
Risk functional, RL,P(g)=
L( x, y, g ( x))dP( x, y)
X Y
L( x, y, g ( x))dP( y / x)dPX
XY
Population Regression functional /classifier, g* RL,P ( g * ) inf RL,P ( g )
g: X Y
P is chosen by nature , L is chosen by the scientist
Both RL,P(g*) and g* are uknown
From sample D, we will select gD by a learning
method(???)
22
Empirical risk minimization
Empirical Risk functional,
Problems of
empirical risk
minimization
R L ,P ( g )
n
=
L( x, y, g ( x))dPn ( x, y )
X Y
L( x, y, g ( x))dPn ( y / x) dPn X
XY
1 n
L( xi , yi , g ( xi ))
n i 1
23
What Can We Do?
We can restrict the set of functions over which we
minimize empirical risk functionals
modify the criterion to be minimized (e.g. adding a penalty
for `complicated‘ functions). We can combine two.
Regularization
Structural risk
Minimization
24
Regularized Error Function
In linear regression, we minimize the error function:
1 l
2
2
( f ( xi ) yi ) w
2l i 1
2
Replace the quadratic error function by Є-insensitive error
l
function:
1 2
C E ( f ( xi ) y ) w
2
i 1
An example of Є-insensitive error function:
25
Linear SVR: Derivation
Meaning of equation 3
26
Linear SVR: Derivation
vs.
●
● ●
●
●
●
Complexity
Sum of errors
●
Case I:
“tube”
complexity
Case II:
“tube”
complexity
27
Linear SVR: Derivation
C is small
● ●
●
●
●
●
• The role
of C
C is big
●●
●
●
●
●
●
●
Case I:
“tube”
complexity
Case II:
“tube”
complexity
28
Linear SVR: derivation
●
● ●
●
●
●
Subject to:
●
29
Lagrangian
Minimize:
l
l
L
0 w ( n n* ) xn
w
n 1
l
L
0 ( n n* ) 0
b
n 1
L
0 n n C
n
L
0 an* n* C
*
n
l
f(x)=<w,x>=
l
( n ) xn , x ( n n* ) xn , x
n 1
*
n
n 1
Dual var. αn,αn*,μn,μ*n >=0
l
l
1 2 l
* *
L C ( n ) w ( n n n n ) n ( n yn w, xn b) n* ( n* yn w, xn b)
2
n 1
n 1
n 1
n 1
*
n
30
Dual Form of Lagrangian
Maximize:
1 l
W ( a, a )
2 n 1
0 n C
*
l
(
m 1
l
n
l
)( m ) xn , xm ( n ) ( n n* ) yn
*
n
*
m
n 1
*
n
n 1
0 n* C
l
(
n 1
n
n* ) 0
Prediction can be made using:
l
f ( x) ( n ) x, xn b
n 1
*
n
???
31
How to determine b?
Karush-Kuhn-Tucker (KKT) conditions implies( at the
optimal solutions:
n ( n yn w, xn b) 0
( yn w, xn b) 0
(C n ) n 0
Support vectors are
*
n
*
n
(C ) 0
*
n
*
n
points that lie on the
boundary or outside the
tube
These equations implies many important things.
32
Important Interpretations
i 0, i.e.i 0 (why??)
*
i
*
i
i 0 i 0,
and i* 0
i* 0
i* C n* yn w, xn b 0
n* w, xn b yn
w, xn b yn
33
Support Vector: The Sparsity
of SV Expansion
i 0 yi f ( xi )
0 f ( xi ) yi
*
i
and
yi f ( xi ) i 0
f ( xi ) yi
*
i
0
34
Maximize:
1 l
W ( , )
2 n 1
0 n C
*
Dual Form of Lagrangian
(Nonlinear case)
l
(
m 1
l
n
l
)( m ) k ( xn , xm ) ( n ) ( n n* ) yn
*
n
*
m
n 1
*
n
n 1
0 n* C
l
*
(
i i)0
i 1
Prediction can be made using:
l
f ( x) (an an* )k ( x, xn ) b
n 1
35
Non-linear SVR: derivation
Subject to:
36
Non-linear SVR: derivation
Subject to:
Saddle point of L has to be found:
min with respect to
max with respect to
37
Non-linear SVR: derivation
...
38
What is Differentiation?
f,a nonlinear function
U
A Banach Space
V,
Another
B-space
Differentiation is nothing but local linearization
In differentiation we approximate a non-linear
function locally by a (continuous) linear function
39
Fréchet Derivative
f ( x h) f ( x) f ( x)h
0
Definition 1 hLt
0
h
| f ( x h) f ( x) f ( x)h |
Lt
0
h 0
|h|
It
can be easily generalized to Banach space valued
B ,
function, f: B ,
1
1
2
2
|| f ( x h) f ( x) f ( x)h ||2
Lt
0
h0
|| h ||1
f (x ) : B 1 B 2 is a linear map. It can be shown,.
every linear map between infinite-dimensional spaces is not
always continuous.
40
Frécehet Derivative
We have just mentioned that Fréchet recognized , the definition 1
could be easily generalized to normed spaces in the following
way:
lim
h 0
f ( x h) f ( x) df ( x)(h)
h1
2
0
f ( x h) f ( x) df ( x)(h)
lim
0 ... ... ... ... (2)
h 0
h1
Where and the set of all continuous linear functions between
B1and B2 If we write, the remainder of f at x+h, ;
41
Rem(x+h)= f(x+h)-f(x)-df(x)(h)
S Derivative
Then 2 becomes
lim
h 0
Re m( x h)
h1
2
0
Re m( x h)
lim
0 ... ... .... ... (3)
h 0
h1
Soon the definition is generalized (S-differentiation ) in general
topological vector spaces in such a way ; i) a particular case of the
definition becomes equivalent to the previous definition when ,
domain of f is a normed space, ii) Gateaux derivative remains the
weakest derivative in all types of S-differentiation.
42
S Derivatives
Definition 2
Let S be a collection of subsets of B1 , let t R. Then f is Sdifferentiable at x with derivative df(x) L( B1 , B2 ) if A S
Re m( x h)
0 as t 0 uniformly in h A
t
Definition 3
When S= all singletons of B1, f is called Gâteaux differentiable
with Gâteaux derivative . When S= all compact subsets of B1, f is
called Hadamard or compactly differentiable with Hadamard or
compact derivative . When S= all bounded subsets of B1, f is
called or boundedly differentiable with or bounded derivative .
43
Equivalent Definitions of Fréchet derivative
(a) For each bounded set, E B1 ,
uniformly
h E
R( x th)
0 as t 0 in R,
t
(b) For each sequence,{hn } B1 and each sequence {tn } R /{0} 0 ;
R( x tn hn )
0 as n
tn
44
(c) R( x h) 0 as h 0
h1
(d) R( x th) 0 as t 0 Uniformly in
h {h B1 : h 1 1}
R ( x th)
0 as t 0 Uniformly in
t
h {h B1 : h 1 1}
t
(e)
Statisticians generally uses this form or its some slight
modification
45
Relations among Usual Forms of Definitions
DG (x) Set of Gateaux differentiable function at x DG (x) set
of Hadamad differentiable function at x DG (x) set Frechet
differentiable function x. In application to find Frechet or
Hadamard derivative generally we shout try first to determine
the form of derivative deducing Gateaux derivative acting on
h,df(h) for a collection of directions h which span B1. This
reduces to computing the ordinary derivative (with respect to
R) of the mapping t f ( x th) at t 0,which is much related
to influence function, one of the central concepts in robust
statistics. It can be easily shown that,
(i) When B1=R with usual norm, they will three coincide
(ii) When B1, a finite dimensional Banach space, Frechet and
46
Hadamard derivative are equal. The two coincide with familiar
total derivative.
Properties of Fréchet derivative
Hadamard
diff. implies continuity but Gâteaux does
not.
Hadamard diff. satisfies chain rule but Gâteaux does
not.
Meaningful Mean Value Theorem, Inverse Function
Theorem, Taylor’s Theorem and Implicit Function
Theorem have been proved for Fréchet derivative
47
T [(1 )F x ] T (F )
IF (T , x ; F ) lt
0
T [(F ( x F )] T (F )
= lt
0
48
T (F ) (x )dF
Counting
Lebesgue
T (F ) (x )dF (x ) f (x )dx
(x ) (x )dF
i 1
i
X T ( Fn ) xdFn
49
Mathematical Foundations of
Robust Statistics
d 1(F,G) <δ
d 2(T(F),T(G))
<ε
T(G)≈T(F)+ TF (G F )
1
n (T(G)-T(F))≈ n TF (G F )
1
50
Mathematical Foundations
of Robust Statistics
51
Mathematical Foundations
of Robust Statistics
52
Mathematical Foundations
of Robust Statistics
53
Given a Measurable Space (W,F),
There exist many measures on F.
If W is the real line, the standard measure is “length”.
That is, the measure of each interval is its length. This
is known as “Lebesgue measure”.
The -algebra must contain intervals. The smallest algebra that contains all open sets (and hence intervals) is
call the “Borel” -algebra and is denoted B.
A course in real analysis will deal a lot with the measurable
space (, B) .
54
Given a Measurable Space (W,F),
A measurable space combined with a measure is called a
measure space. If we denote the measure by , we would
write the triple: (W,F,.
Given a measure space (W,F,, if we decide instead to use a
different measure, say u, then we call this a “change of
measure”. (We should just call this using another measure!)
Let and u be two measures on (W,F), then
u is “absolutely continuous” with respect to if
( A) 0 u ( A) 0 (Notation u )
u and are “equivalent” if
( A) 0 u ( A) 0
55
The Radon-Nikodym Theorem
If u<< then u is actually the integral of a function wrt .
d
du
g
du
d
g
du
du
du
d gd
d
du
u ( A) du
d gd
d
A
A
A
u ( A) gd
A
g is known as the RadonNikodym derivative and denoted:
d
du
g
d
56
The Radon-Nikodym Theorem
If u<< then u is actually the integral of a function wrt .
Idea of proof: Create the function through its superlevel sets
Consider the set function (this is actually a signed measure)
(u )( A) u ( A) ( A)
Choose and let A be the largest set such that
u ( A) ( A) 0 for all A A
(You must prove such an A exists.)
Then A is the -superlevel set of g.
Now, given superlevel sets, we can construct a function by:
g ( ) sup{ | A }
57
The Riesz Representation Theorem:
All continuous linear functionals on Lp are given by integration
q
against a function g L with 1p 1q 1
That is, let L : Lp be a cts. linear functional.
y L( f )
Then: L( f )
fgd
Note, in L2 this becomes:
L( f ) fgd f , g
58
The Riesz Representation Theorem:
All continuous linear functionals on Lp are given by integration
q
against a function g L with 1p 1q 1
What is the idea behind the proof:
Linearity allows you to break things into building blocks,
operate on them, then add them all together.
What are the building blocks of measurable functions.
Indicator functions! Of course!
Let’s define a set valued function from indicator functions:
u ( A) L(1A )
59
The Riesz Representation Theorem:
All continuous linear functionals on Lp are given by integration
q
against a function g L with 1p 1q 1
A set valued function u ( A) L(1A )
How does L operate on simple functions
n
n
n
i 1
i 1
i 1
L( ) L( i 1Ai ) i L(1Ai ) iu ( A)
This looks like an integral with u the measure! L( ) du
But, it is not too hard to show that u is a (signed) measure.
(countable additivity follows from continuity).
Furthermore, u<<. Radon-Nikodym then says du=gd.
60
The Riesz Representation Theorem:
All continuous linear functionals on Lp are given by integration
q
against a function g L with 1p 1q 1
A set valued function u ( A) L(1A )
How does L operate on simple functions
n
n
n
i 1
i 1
i 1
L( ) L( i 1Ai ) i L(1Ai ) iu ( A)
This looks like an integral with u the measure! L ( ) gd
For measurable functions it follows from limits and continuity.
L( ) fgd
The details are left as an “easy” exercise for the reader...
61
A probability measure P is a measure that satisfies P(W) 1
That is, the measure of the whole space is 1.
A random variable is a measurable function.
X ( )
The expectation of a random variable is its integral:
E ( X ) XdP
A density function is the Radon-Nikodym derivative wrt
Lebesgue measure:
dP
fX
E ( X ) XdP xf X ( x)dx
dx
62
A probability measure P is a measure that satisfies P(W) 1
That is, the measure of the whole space is 1.
In finance we will talk about expectations with respect
to different measures.
P
E P ( X ) XdP
Q
E Q ( X ) XdQ
And write expectations in terms of the different measures:
dP
E P ( X ) XdP X
dQ XdQ E Q ( X )
dQ
dP
or dP dQ
where
dQ
63