lecture 1 - FMT-HANU
Download
Report
Transcript lecture 1 - FMT-HANU
LECTURE 10 &11
Functions of Several Variables
Objectives
2
Functions of Several Variables
Partial Derivatives
Second Partial Derivatives
Optimization
Functions of Several Variables
3
A function f(x,y) of two variables x and y is a rule that
assigns a number to each pair of values for the
variables
f(x,y)
= ex(x2+2y)
f(3,5)=
f(5,3)=
f(x,y,z)
= 5xy2z
f(1,3,5)=
f(1,5,3)=
Functions of Several Variables
4
Example: A store sells butter at $2.50 per kg and
margarine at $1.40 per kg.
The revenue from the sale of x kg of butter and y kg
of margarine is given by the function
f(x,y) = 2.5x + 1.4y;
Determine and interpret f(200,300).
Domain
5
Z= x2+y2
𝑥
Z=
𝑦
Z= 1 − (x2+y2)
Graph – 3D co-ordinate system.
6
Production Functions in Economics
7
Cost of manufacturing process can be classified into
two types: Labor (L) and Capital (K).
A manufacturer normally has control over the relative
portion s of labor and capital.
Maximize
labor usage, reduce capital
Minimize labor, need more capital.
f(L,K) : the number of units produced using L labor and
K capital f(L,K) = CLAK(1-A)
Such function is called Cobb-Douglas production
function
Example
8
Suppose that during a certain time period the number
of units of goods produced when utilizing x units of
labor and y units of capital is f(x,y) = 60x3/4y1/4.
How
many units of goods will be produced by using 81
units of labor and 16 units of capital
Show that whenever the amounts of labor and capital
being used are doubled, so is the production. (Economists
say that the production function has “constant returns to
scale”).
Solution
9
Level Curve
10
Example
11
Partial Derivatives
12
𝑧 = 𝑓 𝑥, 𝑦
𝜕𝑧
𝑓 𝑥+∆𝑥,𝑦 −𝑓 𝑥,𝑦
= lim
𝜕𝑥 ∆𝑥→0
∆𝑥
𝜕𝑧 𝜕𝑓
, , 𝑧 x, 𝑓 x
𝜕𝑥 𝜕𝑥
𝜕𝑧
𝑓 𝑥,𝑦+∆𝑦 −𝑓 𝑥,𝑦
=𝑓 = lim
𝜕𝑦 𝑦 ∆𝑦→0
∆𝑦
𝜕𝑧 𝜕𝑓
, ,
𝜕𝑦 𝜕𝑦
𝑧y, 𝑓y
Partial Derivatives
13
The derivative of f(x,y) with respect to x is the
derivative of f(x,y) where y is treated as a constant
and f(x,y) is considered as a function of x alone.
Similar definition for partial derivative of f(x,y) with
respect to y.
Partial Derivative as Rate of Change.
Example
14
𝑓 𝑥, 𝑦 = 2𝑥 + 3𝑦
𝑓𝑥 =
𝑓𝑦=
𝑓 𝑥, 𝑦 = 2𝑥2 + 3𝑥𝑦 + 𝑦
𝑓𝑥 =
𝑓𝑦=
𝑓 𝑥, 𝑦 = 3𝑥𝑒𝑦
𝑓𝑥 =
𝑓𝑦=
Example
15
Production function f(x,y) = 60x3/4y1/4.
Find partial derivatives with respect to x and y.
Evaluate them at x = 81, y = 16
Interpret the numbers computed above.
Marginal
productivity of labor
Marginal productivity of capital
Solution
16
Partial Derivatives
17
Let f(x,y) be a function of two variables. Then if h and
k are small we have
f
( a, b).h
x
f
f ( a, b k ) f ( a, b)
( a, b).k
y
f ( a h, b) f ( a, b)
Example
18
A farmer can produce f(x,y) = 200 (6x2+y2)1/2
units of products by utilizing x units of labor and y
units of capital. (The capital is sued to rent or
purchase land, materials and equipment).
Calculate
the marginal productivities of labor and capital
when x = 10 and y = 5.
Let h be a small number. Determine the approximate
effect on production of changing labor from 10 to 10 + h
units while keeping capital fixed at 5 units.
Estimate the change in production when labor decreases
from 10 to 9.5 units and capital stays fixed at 5 units.
Solution
19
Second Derivative
20
The partial derivative of fx with respect to x is
the second derivative of f(x,y).
We have similar definitions (and their notations) for
2 f
2 f
2 f
2 f
,
,
,
.
2
2
x
y
xy yx
Remark: Almost all functions f(x,y) encountered in
applications have the
property
2
2
f
f
xy yx
Example
21
𝑓 𝑥, 𝑦 = 3𝑥𝑒𝑦
𝑓𝑥=
𝑓𝑦=
𝑓𝑥𝑥=
𝑓𝑥𝑦=
𝑓𝑦𝑥=
𝑓𝑦y=
Extreme Points
22
If f(x,y) has either a local maximum or minimum at
(x,y) = (a,b) then
f
(a, b) 0 and
x
f
( a, b) 0
y
Example 1
23
f(x,y) =x2+y2
Example 2
24
f(x,y) =1-(x2+y2)
Example 3
25
f(x,y) =x2-y2
Second Derivative Test
26
Suppose f(x,y) is a function and (a,b) is a point at which
and let
f
f
( a, b ) 0 &
(a, b) 0,
x
y
f f 2 f
D( x, y ) 2 * 2
x
y
xy
2
2
2
Second Derivative Test
27
If D(a,b) > 0 and second derivative of x > 0 then
f(x,y) has local minimum at (a,b)
If D(a,b) > 0 and second derivative of x < 0 then
f(x,y) has local maximum at (a,b)
If D(a,b) < 0 then f(x,y) is not local at (a,b)
If D(a,b) = 0 then no conclusion can be drawn.
Second Derivative Test
28
fx(a,b)=0
D>0
A<0
fy(a,b)=0
A=fxx(a,b)
D>0 A>0
B=fxy(a,b)
C=fyy(a,b) D<0
D=0
Example 1
29
f(x,y) =x2+y2
Example 2
30
f(x,y) =1-(x2+y2)
Example 3
31
f(x,y) =x2-y2
Example 4
32
f(x,y) = x3 – 3xy + 0.5y2 + 8
Example 5
33
A monopolist manufactures and sells two competing
products, call then I and II, that cost $30 and $20 per
unit, respectively, to produce. The revenue from
marketing x units of product I and y units of product II
is 98x + 112y – 0.04xy – 0.1x2 – 0.2y2. Find the
values of x and y that maximize the monopolist’s
profits.
Solution
34
Example 6
35
(Price Discrimination): A monopolist markets his product
into two countries and can charge different amounts in
each country. Let x be the number of units to be sold
in the first country and y be the number of units to be
sold in the second country. Due to the laws of demand,
the monopolist must set the price at 97 – (x/10)
dollars in the first country and 83 – (y/20) dollars in
the second country in order to sell al the units. The cost
of producing these units is 20,000 + 3(x+y). Find the
values of x and y that maximize the profit.
Solution
36
Constrained Optimization
37
Problem: Let f(x,y) and g(x,y) be functions of two
variables. Find values of x and y that maximize (or
minimize) the objective function f(x,y) and that also
satisfy the constraint equation g(x,y) = 0.
E.g.1: Minimize 42x + 28y, subject to the constraint
600 – xy = 0, x,y>0
Constrained Optimization
38
We can solve the equation g(x,y) = 0 for one variable
in terms of the other and substitute the resulting
expression into f(x,y)
If we cannot solve the equation g(x,y) = 0 for one
variable in terms of the other.
Lagrange: Invent “Lagrange multipliers”
Lagrange multipliers
39
Basic idea: Replace f(x,y) by an auxiliary function of
three variables F(x,y,λ) defined as: F(x,y,λ) = f(x,y) +
λg(x,y).
Theorem: Suppose that, subject to the constraint g(x,y)
= 0, the function f(x,y) has a relative maximum or
minimum at (x,y) = (a,b). Then there is a value of λ,
say λ = c, such that the partial derivatives of F(x,y, λ)
all equal to zero at (x,y, λ) = (a,b,c).
Example 1
40
Using Lagrange multipliers, minimize 42x + 28y,
subject to the constraint 600 – xy = 0, where x and y
are restricted to positive values.
Example 2
41
Suppose that x units of labor and y units of capital
can produce f(x,y) = 60x3/4y1/4 units of a certain
product. Also suppose that each unit of labor costs
$100, whereas each unit of capital costs $200.
Assume that $30,000 is available to spend on
production. How many units of labor and how many
units of capital should be utilized in order to maximize
production.
Solution
42
Example
43
Lagrange multiplier λ can be interpreted as the
marginal productivity of money. That is, if one
additional dollar is available, then approximately λ
units of the product can be produced.
Example
44
Economics law: If labor and capital are at their
optimal levels, then the ratio of their marginal
productivities equals the ratio of their unit costs.
Example 3
45
Use Lagrange multipliers to find the three positive
numbers whose sum is 15 and whose product is as
large as possible.
Utility Maximization Problem
46
A consumer makes consumption decision based on his
preferences (utility function) given his limited income.
Let
Good
1 consumption: x
Good 2 consumption: y
Price for good 1: px
Price for good 2: py
Income level: M
Total expenditure: xpx + ypy
Utility maximization problem
47
Total expenditure: xpx + ypy has to be within income
xpx + ypy ≤ M. If the consumer spends all his
income in good 1 and good 2 then xpx + ypy = M.
This is the budget constraint.
Regions:
Inside
budget line: feasible.
Outside budget line: infeasible.
Problem: The consumer maximizes u = U(x,y) subject to
the budget constraint xpx + ypy = M.
Utility Maximization Problem
48
Example: Consider an agent who consumes Good 1
and Good 2. We denote the amount of those goods
by x and y, respectively. The utility function of this
agent is given by
U
= U(x,y) = x1/2y1/2
This agent has income of 12 and does not save. If the
prices of Good 1 and Good 2 are px = 2 and py = 1,
respectively, what is the amount of goods this agent
chooses to consume?
Conclusion
49
Functions of Several Variables
Partial Derivatives
Second Partial Derivatives
Optimization