Transcript Chapter 17
Chapter 17
Monopoly
1*
Market Power
In many situations, competition is not intense
A firm has market power when it can profitably charge
a price that is above its marginal cost
Most firms have some market power, though it may be
very slight
Depends on whether their competitors’ products are close
substitutes
Two market structures in which firms have market
power:
A monopoly market has a single seller
An oligopoly market has a few, but not many, producers
3*
How Do Firms Become
Monopolists?
Firms get to be monopolists in various ways:
Government grants a monopoly position to a firm
(cable TV companies in local communities, drug
patents)
Economies of scale (concrete supply in a small
town)
Being first to produce a new product (iPod)
Owning all of an essential input (De Beers diamond
producer)
4*
Figure 17.1: Scale Economies
and Monopoly
Monopolist can make
a profit because AC
lies below the
demand curve at
some quantities
Two firms cannot
make positive profits
AC lies above Dhalf for
all quantities
*
Monopoly Pricing
Monopolist will choose the price that maximizes its
profit, given the demand for its product
Whenever the firm’s profit-maximizing sales quantity is
positive, marginal revenue equals marginal cost at that sales
quantity
Marginal cost curve applies as usual
Need to examine the shape of the marginal revenue
curve
Recall that a firm’s marginal revenue curve captures
the additional revenue it gets from the marginal units it
sells, measured on a per-unit basis
6*
Marginal Revenue for a
Monopolist
An increase in sales quantity (Q) changes revenue in two ways
Firm sells Q additional units of output, each at a price of P(Q),
the output expansion effect
Firm also has to lower price as dictated by the demand curve;
reduces revenue earned from the original (Q-Q) units of output,
the price reduction effect
The overall effect on marginal revenue is:
So the price reduction effect makes the monopolist’s marginal
revenue less than price
7*
Figure 17.2: Marginal Revenue
and Price
*
Monopoly Profit Maximization
When a monopolist maximizes its profit by selling a
positive amount, its marginal revenue must equal its
marginal cost at that quantity
If marginal revenue exceeded marginal cost the firm would be
better off selling more
If marginal revenue were less than marginal cost the firm would
be better off selling less
Two-step procedure for finding the profit-maximizing sales
quantity
Step 1: Quantity Rule
Identify positive sales quantities at which MR=MC
If more than one, find one with highest profit
Step 2: Shut-Down Rule
Check whether the quantity from Step 1 yields higher profit than
shutting down
9*
Figure 17.4: Monopoly Profit
Maximization
*
Markup
A monopolist facing a downward sloping demand
curve will set its P above MC
Firm in a perfectly competitive market sets price = MC,
meaning that the firm has no market power
Extent to which P exceeds MC is a measure of
monopolist’s market power
A firm’s markup, price-cost margin, or Lerner
index equals the difference between its P and its MC,
as a % of its P
11
*
Markup
A monopolist’s markup at its profit-maximizing
P always equals the reciprocal of the elasticity
of demand, times negative one
The less elastic the demand curve, the greater
the firm’s markup over its marginal cost
When demand is less elastic, raising the price
is more attractive because fewer sales are lost
This also implies that demand must be elastic
at the profit-maximizing price
12
*
Welfare Effects of
Monopoly Pricing
By charging a P above MC, the monopolist makes
consumers worse off than under perfect competition
Consumers who buy the product pay more for it
Some who would have bought it under perfect competition will
not buy it at the higher price
Welfare effects of monopoly pricing:
Firm gains
Consumers lose
Deadweight loss incurred
Deadweight loss from monopoly pricing is the amount
by which aggregate surplus falls short of its maximum
possible level, which is attained in a competitive market
13
*
Figure 17.5: Welfare Effects of
Monopoly Pricing
*
Distinguishing Monopoly from
Perfect Competition
Existence of more than one firm in a market
does not guarantee perfect competition
How can we tell whether multiple firms in a
market are behaving like price takers or
colluding and acting like a monopoly?
Easy to answer if we could observe MCs and
compare to P
Monopolists and perfectly competitive
industries behave differently in responses to
changes in demand and changes in costs
15
*
Response to Changes in Demand
Monopolist’s profit-maximizing price depends
on elasticity of demand
Price in perfectly competitive market depends
on level of demand
If elasticity of demand changes but level of
demand does not, provides a way to
distinguish between market structures
16
*
Figure 17.7: Response to a
Change in Demand
*
Response to Changes in Cost
How do monopolies and perfectly competitive markets
differ in their response to changes in costs?
Consider the case of a marginal cost increase by a
given amount at every level of output
Example: a specific tax, T, on firms
The pass-through rate is the increase in P that occurs
in response to a small increase in MC, measured per
dollar of increase in MC
In a competitive market, the pass-through rate is never
greater than one (cannot increase P by more than T)
The monopolist’s pass-through rate depends on the
shape of the D curve
Can be greater than one with a constant-elasticity demand
curve:
18
*
P=(Ed / (Ed+1)) MC
or: PM is a multiple of its MC
if Ed=-2, then P=2MC
19
*
Price Paid by Consumers ($/gallon)
Effects of a Specific Tax – Shifting the
Supply Curve
ST
Increase in
Consumer Cost
per Gallon
S
Po + T
Pb
B
T
A
Po
Ps = Pb - T
Decrease in
Firms’ Receipts
per Gallon
D
QT
Qo
*
Gallons of Gas per Month
Nonprice Effects of Monopoly:
Product Quality
Product quality is a decision firms make
Raising a product’s quality increases the consumer’s
willingness to pay
Producing a higher-quality product usually costs more
The firm must decide whether the extra benefit is worth the
extra cost
How does the quality provided by a monopolist
compare to the level that would maximize aggregate
surplus?
If different consumers value quality differently, the
monopolist may not choose to offer the quality that
maximizes aggregate surplus
May over- or under-produce quality
21
*
Nonprice Effects of Monopoly:
Advertising
Spending on advertising is another important decision for many
firms
Because the monopolist’s marginal cost is less than the price,
each additional sale increases its profit
Firms in perfectly competitive markets have no individual incentive
to advertise
Each firm perceives itself as capable of selling as much as its desires
at the market price
Marginal benefit of advertising equals the increase in sales times
the firm’s profit on additional sales
At the profit-maximizing level of advertising, this marginal benefit
must equal the extra dollar expended
For a monopolist, the ratio of the amount spend on advertising to
the firm’s total sales revenue, the advertising-sales ratio, equals
the advertising elasticity divided by the elasticity of demand, times
negative one
22
*
Nonprice Effects of Monopoly:
Investments
Firms can also make investments in an effort to become a
monopolist
Example: cable TV firms lobbying government officials to award them
franchises
If firms compete to become a monopolist, they will spend up to the
full monopoly profit less avoidable fixed costs
If spend on socially wasteful things (e.g., golf outings for local
officials) the loss from monopoly may be larger than deadweight loss
and include all monopoly profit
Rent seeking is socially useless effort devoted to securing a
monopoly position
Welfare effects of monopoly need not always be so bad
Expenditures firms make to gain monopoly positions can be socially
valuable (e.g., R&D spending in the search for patentable drugs)
23
*
Monopsony
Read monopsony section: p:648-652
24
*
Regulation of Monopolies
Deadweight loss from monopoly pricing provides a
justification for government intervention
Government actions that keep prices closer to MC can
protect consumers and increase economic efficiency
Intervention can take many forms
Antitrust legislation (see Chapter 19)
Direct regulation of prices
Price regulation (not common in U.S. today)
More prevalent in the past
Still used for electricity, natural gas, local telephone service
More common in some other countries
25
*
Why Are Some Monopolies
Regulated?
Regulation arises out of political pressure and
economic concern about market dominance
When governments create monopolies they may then
regulate them to deal with the negative consequences
May create a monopoly to ensure that goods are
produced at least cost
A market is a natural monopoly when a good is
produced most economically through a single firm
Average cost falls as quantity increases
Second firm may enter but this would cause costs to rise
Government can designate one firm to be the provider
Institute price regulation to protect consumers
26
*
Figure 17.11: A Natural Monopoly
*