public good - McGraw Hill Higher Education
Download
Report
Transcript public good - McGraw Hill Higher Education
Chapter 20
Externalities and Public Goods
McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Main Topics
Externalities and inefficiency
Remedies for externalities: the private
sector
Remedies for externalities: the public
sector
Common property resources
Public goods
20-2
Externalities
Competitive markets may not allocate resources
efficiently when the assumptions of the model are
violated
Example: assumed that each consumer’s well-being
depends only on her own consumption
An action creates an externality if it affects someone
with whom the decision-maker has not engaged in a
related market transaction
Negative externality if it harms someone else
Polluting causes health problems in a community, neglecting a
garden reduces neighbors’ home values
Positive externality if it benefits someone else
Pollution abatement reduces health effects on community,
carefully tended garden raises the value of surrounding homes
20-3
Negative Externalities and
Inefficiency
Presence of a negative externality in a competitive
market will usually allocate economic resources
inefficiently
An external cost is the economic harm that a negative
externality imposes on others
Each firm produces up to the point at which its
marginal cost curve equals the market price
But socially efficient level of production for any
particular firm equates marginal social cost and
marginal social benefit
Marginal social cost = marginal cost to the producer + marginal
external cost
Therefore the firm’s equilibrium production level is
socially excessive and inefficient
20-4
Negative Externalities and
Inefficiency
Similar result holds for the entire market
When firms ignore external costs, they are
willing to produce too much output at any given
price
The good is priced too cheaply in equilibrium
Because output is priced incorrectly, consumers
demand too much
The externality creates deadweight loss
Society’s loss equals the vertical distance between
the demand curve and the marginal social cost
curve
20-5
Figure 20.1: Negative Externality
in a Competitive Market
20-6
Positive Externalities and
Inefficiency
Competitive equilibria are inefficient when
either positive or negative externalities are
present
An external benefit is the economic gain that
a positive externality provides to others
Firm output will be inefficiently low from
society’s perspective
Like a negative externality, a positive
externality creates deadweight loss
20-7
Figure 20.2: Positive Externality in
a Competitive Market
20-8
Remedies for Externalities:
Private Sector
Whenever the allocation of resources is inefficient it is
possible to arrange mutually beneficial trades
Private parties thus have incentives to identify
inefficiencies and negotiate solutions
When private negotiations fail to address market
failures associated with externalities, government
policies can potentially improve economic efficiency
Policies that support markets (e.g., establishing clear property
rights)
Quantity controls (e.g., emissions standards)
Policies that correct private incentives (e.g., taxes, fees,
subsidies)
20-9
Property Rights and Negotiation
Outcome of a negotiation depends on the parties’
property rights
Party who holds the relevant property rights is in a
stronger bargaining position
Usually emerges with a more favorable deal
Assignment of property rights does not affect the level
of pollution but does affect profits
Coase theorem: regardless of how property rights are
assigned, voluntary agreements will remedy
externalities
If bargaining is frictionless
Sometimes used as a justification for laissez faire
policies
Coase did not believe that bargaining is frictionless
20-10
Limitations of Bargaining
Every externality can be traced to missing markets
Private negotiations lead to transactions that the
parties would have made if the required markets
weren’t missing
Many factors that cause externalities also hinder
bargaining
Bargaining can be impractical
Difficult logistics, substantial time and effort
Property rights may be ambiguous
Limited information can lead to an impasse
Contracts may be difficult to enforce
20-11
Quantity Controls
Government can attempt to address an externality by
regulating the activity that produces it
An emissions standard is a legal limit on the amount
of pollution that a person or company can produce
When engaged in a particular activity
Example: Aircraft noise abatement
Setting a socially efficient abatement standard requires
information about abatement costs and benefits
Private parties may have an incentive to exaggerate
their costs (or benefits)
Government may have trouble learning the truth
Can lead to an inefficient standard and deadweight loss
20-12
Policies that Correct
Private Incentives
Some policies address externalities by forcing people
to internalize external costs and benefits
Impose taxes or fees, provide subsidies, expose
decision-makers to legal liability
Pigouvian taxation involves the use of taxes or fees
to remedy negative externalities
A Pigouvian tax forces a decision-maker to internalize
the marginal external costs associated with her activity
Weigh it against marginal benefit
Make a socially efficient decision
Ideal Pigouvian tax reproduces the price that the good
in question would command in an efficient competitive
equilibrium
20-13
Figure 20.5: Pigouvian Tax on Noise
Airline produces noise
up to the point where
MCA equals the tax of
$10,000 per decibel
Socially efficient
outcome is achieved,
with noise at 80
decibels
20-14
Liability Rules
Another mechanism for addressing negative
externalities
Under a liability rule a party who takes an action that
harms others must compensate the affected parties for
their losses
Liability rules induce decision-makers to internalize all
external costs
Lead to efficient choices
In some cases, the government needs less information
to effectively use a liability rule than an emissions
standard or Pigouvian tax
Liability rules raise other difficulties because of their
legal nature
20-15
Pitfalls for Policies that Correct
Private Incentives
Liability rules and Pigouvian taxes both force decisionmakers to internalize harm caused to others
But harms often have multiple causes
In such cases efforts to correct private incentives can
lead to inefficiency
Typical liability rule holds one source of external cost
accountable
Inefficient if more than one group’s choices contribute to the
external costs
Ideal rule would force all parties contributing to the
externality to bear a portion of the social costs
20-16
Consequences of Policy Errors
Errors in setting a tax vs. a standard may have different
implications for efficiency
This consideration can provide a reason for preferring one
approach over the other
Which policy is better?
Depends on the slopes of the marginal social cost (MSC) and
marginal cost of abatement (MCA) curves
Standard is superior when the MCA curve is relatively
flat and the MSC curve is relatively steep
Tax is superior when the MCA curve is relatively steep
and the MSC curve is relatively flat
20-17
Figure 20.8: Consequences of
Policy Errors
20-18
Minimizing Total Cost
of Abatement
External costs of pollution may depend on the total
emission of many parties
In so, an emissions tax guarantees that reduction in the
overall level of pollution will be achieved at the lowest
possible cost
Emissions standard does not guarantee this
Each firm will pollute up to the point at which the
marginal cost of abatement equals the tax rate
Firms produce different amounts of pollution but will
share the same marginal cost of abatement
Any change in firms’ emissions that leaves total
pollution unchanged will increase overall abatement
costs
20-19
Figure 20.9: Emissions Tax
20-20
Tradable Emissions Permits
A tradable emissions permit entitles a firm to generate a
specified amount of a given pollutant
Transferable, one firm can sell it to another
Total emissions are limited by the number of permits the
government issues
Enables the government to reduce the level of pollution to any desired
target
Can achieve any given reduction in total emissions at the lowest
possible abatement cost
Competitive market for permits may emerge
Each firm will generate pollution up to the point at which marginal
cost of abatement equals the market price of a permit
Note that the market does not set the level of pollution
20-21
Common Property Resources
A common property resource is a resource that more than one
person is free to use without payment
Examples: Lakes, air, oceans
Generally, each person’s use of a common property resource
reduces its value to others
Creates a negative externality
Consider a large lake, the only source of fish for nearby towns,
where anyone can become a fisherman free of charge
The marginal social cost of fishing exceeds the marginal private
cost
Each fisherman fails to account for the fact that his decision to catch
fish reduces the fish population and raises the cost of fishing for
future fishermen
Competitive level of fishing is socially excessive
Remedies for market failures associated with common property
resources are the same as for negative externalities
20-22
Figure 20.13: Common Property
Resources and Overfishing
MSC
Price per pound of fish ($)
2000
1500
Dmarket
Smarket
1000
MEC
500
Qefficient
Qequilib
Fish (pounds)
20-23
Public Goods: Basics
A public good is nonrival and nonexcludable
A good is nonrival if more than one person can
consume it at the same time without affecting its value
to others
Marginal cost of providing it is zero
A good is nonexcludable if there is no way to prevent
a person from consuming it
Examples of public goods: national defense,
construction of lighthouses
Governments often provide public goods
Not all goods provided by a government are public goods
20-24
Efficient Provision of Public Goods
Socially efficient level of production is where marginal
social cost equals marginal social benefit
Whether good is private or public
To determine the marginal social benefit of a public
good, add up the gains to all affected individuals
Important difference from process for private good
Sum individual curves vertically for a public good
Example: security patrols on a city block
Three stores would receive marginal benefit of $7.50, $45, and
$40 from the first hour of patrolling
Marginal social benefit is the vertical sum, $92.50, for a
quantity of one hour
20-25
Figure 20.14: Provision of a
Public Good
20-26
Public Goods and Market Failure
If someone decides to contribute to a public good,
other people will benefit
The contribution creates a positive externality
Competitive markets produce too little output when
positive externalities are present
If provision of a public good is left entirely to the
independent actions of private parties, the level of
production will be inefficiently low
Market failure associated with public goods is due to
free riding
A free rider contributes little or nothing to a public
good while benefiting from others’ contributions
20-27
Public Policy Toward Public Goods
Governments address the market failures associated with public
goods in a variety of ways:
Provide some public goods (national defense)
Contribute to non-profit organizations that provide them (public radio
and television)
Subsidize private contributions to many public goods (environmental
protection)
Subsidization often takes the form of tax deductibility for
contributions to charitable causes that support public goods
These are variants of the methods used to address externalities
Efficient public provision of a public good need not entail public
production
Market failure of public goods related to demand, not production
Governments often rely on the private sector to produce public goods
Example: U.S. obtains military equipment from private defense
contractors
20-28
Gathering Reliable Information
To provide a public good efficiently, the government must have
information about individual preferences
Cannot simply ask; answers will depend on who consumers expect to
foot the bill for the public good
A Groves mechanism is a way to set the level of a public good
that induces everyone to report their preferences correctly
Produces a socially efficient outcome
Ask each citizen to report the total benefit he would receive from
the public good
Calculate teach individual’s marginal benefit as though he told the
truth
Each consumer’s contribution toward the public good is based on
the quantity of public good that would be optimal with and without
his reported benefits
Consumer will be worse off if he exaggerates or understates his
benefits than if he tells the truth
Groves mechanism gives consumers a strong incentive to tell the
truth
20-29
Figure 20.15: The Groves Mechanism
20-30
Public Decision-Making
The field of political economy examines the economic
consequences of public sector decision-making
Example: determine whether public intervention is
justified
Weigh the consequences of a market failure against the likely
consequences of a government failure
When markets fail, the public sector may be able to
improve the allocation of resources, in principle
Do democratic mechanisms promote socially efficient
government decision-making?
Assume a policy is overturned if more than 50% of voters
prefer an alternative
20-31
Median Voter Theorem
Median voter theorem: if voters have singlepeaked preferences, a majority of them prefer
the median ideal policy to all others
A voter’s preferences are single-peaked if her
net benefit from an activity increases with the
activity’s level until her ideal is reached
Declines thereafter
Median voter is the voter who has the median
ideal policy among all voters
Majority rule leads to the selection of the
median ideal policy
20-32
Figure 20.16: Majority Rule and
the Level of a Public Good
20-33