Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
Download
Report
Transcript Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
Monopoly
Chapter 12
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 2
Introduction
Monopoly is a market structure in
which a single firm makes up the entire
supply side of the market.
Monopoly is the polar opposite of
perfect competition.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 3
Introduction
Monopolies exist because of barriers to
entry into a market that prevent entry by
new firms.
Barriers to entry include legal barriers
such as a patent, and natural barriers
such as the size of the market that can
support only one firm.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 4
The Key Difference Between
a Monopolist and a Perfect
Competitor
A competitive firm is too small to affect
the price.
It does not have to take into account the
effect of its output decision on the price
it receives.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 5
The Key Difference Between
a Monopolist and a Perfect
Competitor
A competitive firm's marginal revenue is
the market price.
A monopolistic firm’s marginal revenue
is not equal to its price – it takes into
account that in order to sell more it has
to decrease the price of its product.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 6
The Key Difference Between
a Monopolist and a Perfect
Competitor
Monopolist as the only supplier faces
the entire market demand curve.
Therefore, monopoly demand is
downward sloping, and to increase
output the firm must decrease its price.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 7
A Model of Monopoly
How much should a monopoly produce
to maximize its profit?
The
monopolist employs a two-step profit
maximizing process; it chooses quantity
and price.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 8
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output
As in perfect competition, profit for the
monopolist is maximized at a point
where MC = MR.
What is different for a monopolist –
marginal revenue does not equal price;
marginal revenue is below price.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 9
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output
If a monopolist deviates from the output
level at which marginal cost equals
marginal revenue, profits will fall.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 10
Profit Maximization for a Monopolist,
Output Price
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
36
33
30
27
24
21
18
15
12
9
Table 12-1, p 257
TR
MR
TC
MC
0
33
60
81
96
105
108
105
96
81
—
1
2
4
8
16
24
40
56
80
—
33
27
21
15
9
3
–3
–9
–15
47
48
50
54
62
78
102
142
196
278
ATC
Profit
48.00
25.00
18.00
15.50
15.60
17.00
20.29
24.75
30.89
–47
–15
10
27
34
27
6
–37
–102
–197
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 11
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output Graphically
The marginal revenue curve tells us the
additional revenue the firm will get from
an additional unit of output.
The marginal cost curve is a graph of
the change in firm’s total cost as it
changes output.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 12
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output Graphically
To determine the profit-maximizing price
and quantity:
one
first finds output (where MC = MR),
and then
extends a vertical line for that output, up to
the demand curve to find the price.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 13
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output Graphically
If MR > MC, the monopolist gains profit
by increasing output.
If MR < MC, the monopolist gains profit
by decreasing output.
If MC = MR, the monopolist is
maximizing profit.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 14
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output Graphically
The MR = MC condition determines the
quantity a monopolist produces.
That quantity determines the price the
monopolist will charge.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 15
Comparing Monopoly and
Perfect Competition
Profit-maximizing output for the
monopolist, like profit maximizing
output for the competitor in a perfectly
competitive market is where MC = MR.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 16
Comparing Monopoly and
Perfect Competition
Because the monopolist’s marginal
revenue is below its price, its
equilibrium output is less than, and price
is higher than that of a perfectly
competitive market.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 17
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output Graphically, Fig.12-1, p 259
MC
Price
$36
30
24
20.5018
12
6
0
6
12
Monopolist
price and
output
Perfectly competitive
price and output
D
1
2
3
4
5 6
5.17
7
8 9 10
MR
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 18
Finding the monopolist’s
price and output
Draw the firm's marginal revenue curve.
Determine the output the monopolist will
produce by the intersection of the MC
and MR curves.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 19
Finding the monopolist’s
price and output
Determine the price the monopolist will
charge for that output by finding where
the quantity line intersects the demand
curve.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 20
Finding the monopolist’s
price and output, Fig. 12-2a and b, p 260
Price
MC
D
MR
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 21
Finding the monopolist’s
price and output, Fig. 12-2 c and d, p 260
Price
MC
PM
MR
QM
D
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 22
Finding the Monopolist’s
Profit
Determine the average cost at the
profit-maximizing level of output.
Determine the monopolist's profit (loss)
by subtracting average total cost from
average revenue (P) at that level of
output and multiply by the chosen
output.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 23
Monopoly
A monopolist can make a profit, it can
break even, or it can incur a loss.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 24
A Monopolist Making a
Profit, Fig. 12-3, p 261
MC
Price
A
PM
Profit
CM
ATC
B
MR
0
QM
D
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 25
A Monopolist Breaking Even,
Fig. 12-4a, p 262
MC
Price
ATC
PM
MR
0
QM
D
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 26
A Monopolist Making a Loss
Fig. 12-4b, p 262
MC
Price
CM
PM
B
Loss
A
MR
0
ATC
QM
D
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 27
The Welfare Loss from
Monopoly
A single price monopoly creates welfare
losses.
Welfare losses can be illustrated by the
area of consumer and producer surplus
that is lost due to smaller output
produced, compared to output produced
in perfect competition.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 28
The Welfare Loss from
Monopoly
Compare the normal monopolist's
equilibrium to the equilibrium of a
perfect competitor.
Equilibrium in both market structures is
determined by the MC = MR condition.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 29
The Welfare Loss from
Monopoly
But the monopolist's MR is below its
price, thus its equilibrium output is
different from a competitive market.
The welfare loss of a monopolist is
represented by the triangles B and D.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 30
The Welfare Loss from
Monopoly, Fig. 12-5, p 262
Price
MC
PM
C
PC
D
B
A
0
QM
MR
QC
D
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 31
The Welfare Loss from
Monopoly
Welfare loss is often called the
deadweight loss or welfare loss triangle.
It is the geometric representation of the
welfare cost in terms of misallocated
resources that are caused by monopoly.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 32
The Price-Discriminating
Monopolist
Price discrimination is the ability to
charge different prices to different
customers.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 33
The Price-Discriminating
Monopolist
In order to price discriminate, a
monopolist must be able to:
Identify
groups of customers who have
different elasticities of demand;
Separate them in some way; and
Limit their ability to resell its product
between groups.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 34
The Price-Discriminating
Monopolist
A price-discriminating monopolist can
charge customers with more inelastic
demands a higher price.
It can charge customers with more
elastic demands a lower price.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 35
The Price-Discriminating
Monopolist
A perfect price discriminating monopoly
can extract the most consumers are
willing to pay for each unit of the product
it sells.
All consumer surplus is transferred to the
monopolist.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 36
The Price-Discriminating
Monopolist
A perfect price discriminating monopoly
will stop expanding its output when MR
= MC, which corresponds to the
perfectly competitive output.
The deadweight loss is therefore
eliminated under perfect price
discrimination.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 37
Perfect Price Discrimination,
Fig. 12-6, p 265
Price
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
MC
D=MR
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11
MR
Quantity (number of
consumers)
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 38
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
What prevents other firms from entering
the monopolist’s market in response to
profits the monopolist earns?
Monopolies exist because of barriers to
entry.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 39
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
In the absence of barriers to entry, the
monopoly would face competition from
other firms, which would erode its
monopoly position .
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 40
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Some important barriers to entry are:
Economies
of scale,
Set-up costs,
Legislation.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 41
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Economies of scale:
When
production is characterized by
increasing returns to scale, the larger the
firm becomes, the lower its per unit costs
become.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 42
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Economies of scale:
If
significant economies of scale are
possible, it is inefficient to have two
producers because if each produced half of
the output, neither could take advantage of
economies of scale.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 43
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Economies of scale:
A
natural monopoly is an industry in
which one firm can produce at a lower cost
than can two or more firms.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 44
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Economies of scale:
In
cases of natural monopoly, technology is
such that minimum efficient scale is so
large that average total costs fall within the
range of potential output.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 45
A Natural Monopoly, Fig. 12-7b, p 267
Price, Cost
PM
CM
CC
PC
ATC
MC
QM MR
QC D
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 46
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Set-up costs:
In
many industries high set-up costs
characterize production.
The industry may be highly capitalintensive, requiring a large investment in
expensive but highly specialized capital.
Examples are an oil refinery or a diamond
mine.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 47
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Set-up costs:
In
some industries a lot of money may be
spent on advertising.
Heavy advertising creates a barrier to entry
in those cases, such as in the perfume
industry or the automobile industry.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 48
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Legislation:
Monopolies
can also exist as a result of
government charter.
Patents are another way in which
government can grant a company a
monopoly.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 49
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Legislation:
A
patent is a legal protection of technical
innovation that gives the inventor a
monopoly on using the invention.
To encourage research and development of
new products, government gives out
patents for a wide variety of innovations.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 50
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Other barriers to entry:
Sometimes
one company can gain
ownership of some essential aspect of the
production process – a unique input, or
control over a resource.
An example is DeBeers. By controlling the
world-wide distribution network for
diamonds, the company enjoys monopoly
in the diamond industry.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
Monopoly
End of Chapter 12
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.