Monopoly Power in Input Markets

Download Report

Transcript Monopoly Power in Input Markets

Monopoly
Power in Input
Markets
Chapter 17
Slides by Pamela L. Hall
Western Washington University
©2005, Southwestern
Introduction

As a result of their monopoly power in input market (called monopsony power)
 Factor markets diverge from perfectly competitive assumption developed in Chapter
16

In an input market, monopsony, a single buyer for an input, is the polar case of
perfect competition
 An example is a mining firm in a company town
• If you will be employed in this town, you will work for the mine
 Other examples are
• Southern plantation prior to Civil War
• In agricultural regions, a single food processing plant dominating employment for many miles
around

A firm that is a major but not the sole employer is called an oligopsony
 Examples are a number of textile companies in a small town or a university in a
college town

Also possible for a supplier of input to possess monopoly power
 For example, in some labor markets a labor union may have monopoly power
2
Introduction

Our aim in this chapter is to determine efficiency
loss associated with monopoly and monopsony
power in a factor market
 Must first determine firms’ input pricing and employment
decisions under various assumptions


Focus of this investigation is on labor market
We derive a monopsony’s profit-maximizing wage
rate and level of employment
 General condition that a firm equates its marginal
revenue to marginal cost for profit maximization still holds
• However, in this case marginal revenue and marginal cost are
measured as

Additional worker hired rather than additional output produced
3
Introduction

Illustrate inefficiency of monopsony pricing by deadweight loss in total surplus
 A monopoly in the supply of inputs is the same as a monopoly in the supply of output

We investigate a monopoly facing a monopsony
 Called a bilateral monopoly

We discuss labor unions as cartels
 With potential of exerting monopoly power, in terms of their objectives and
effectiveness
• Similar to output-price discrimination, a monopsony may wage discriminate


Rise of monopsony power directed toward labor in 19th century and emergence
of labor unions to counter this power is an ongoing topic of research
Applied economists working for monopsonies are constantly devising new
approaches to determine factor supplier’s reservation price (wage)
 Economists for factor suppliers are always devising methods for determining
demanders’ reservation price
4
Monopsony Wage and
Employment Determination

In 1998 Georgia’s construction industry employed over 346,000 workers
and had revenues in excess of $26 billion
 However, there was a continual shortage of qualified labor
• State’s construction industry could have used an additional 6000 to 8000 workers
each year
 Given this shortage, existing workers were benefiting from higher wages
• A skilled tradesperson earned between $15 to $16 per hour


Construction companies were facing double-digit annual wage increases
Such conditions are characteristic of firms with monopsony power in a
labor market facing an upward-sloping supply curve for labor
 For a firm to hire an additional worker under such conditions, wage rate has
to increase
• Not just for this additional worker but for all workers
 Marginal input cost, MIC, curve is upward sloping and lies above supply
curve
5
Monopsony Wage and
Employment Determination

For example, given a linear inverse labor supply curve, firm’s average
input cost, AIC, is
 AICL = w = a + bL, with b > 0


• w/L = b > 0
For the firm to hire an additional worker, wages for all workers must
increase by b
If total input cost, TIC, is
 TICL = (AICL)L = aL + bL2
• Marginal input cost is



MICL = TICL/L = a + 2bL
MICL/L = 2b > 0
For a linear supply curve, MIC curve is twice as steep as AIC curve
 Bisects this AIC curve and vertical axis
• Illustrated in Figure 17.1
6
Monopsony Wage and
Employment Determination

A monopsony who hires a relatively large share of
available employees faces an upward-sloping
average input cost curve (supply curve) for labor,
the AICL curve
 AICL (wages) is a function of number of workers hired,
w(L)
• Increasing number of workers requires increasing all wages,
w(L)/ L > 0


Corresponds to moving to a higher point on AICL curve
Monopsony will not only pay a higher wage to
additional worker but also to those workers already
employed
 Specifically, TICL = w(L)L
7
Monopsony Wage and
Employment Determination

Using product rule to take derivative with respect to L yields
 MICL = [w(L)L]/L = w + L(w/L) = AICL + L(w/L)
• Marginal input cost for labor (MICL) is equal to AICL plus an adjustment
factor L(w/L)

Adjustment factor accounts for having to pay a higher wage
to those workers already employed
 Under perfect competition in factor market, adjustment factor is zero
• Marginal cost of hiring one more worker is market wage

Firm takes wage rate as given
 For a firm with monopsony power, adjustment factor is positive
• Marginal input cost of hiring an additional worker (MICL) is greater than
wage rate (AICL )
8
Monopsony Wage and
Employment Determination

If marginal unit (in this case MICL), is greater than average
unit (AICL), average is rising
 Relationship between MICL and AICL is illustrated in Figure 17.1
• AICL is rising, so adjustment is positive




Results in MICL > AICL
In terms of elasticity of supply, S = (LS/w)(w/LS), we
represent MICL as
 MICL = wL/L = w + L(w/L) = w[1 + (1/S) = AICL[1 + (1/S)]
When supply is perfectly elastic, supply curve is horizontal
 MICL = AICL (firm is a perfectly competitive employer of labor)
In contrast, when a firm is facing an upward-sloping supply
curve
 Potential for monopsony power exists with MICL > AICL
9
Figure 17.1 Monopsony power in the
labor market resulting in MICL > AICL
10
Profit Maximizing

Suppose a firm with monopsony power in both of its
two variable inputs, L and K, is interested in
maximizing profits
• Subject to a production function


q = f(L, K)
Forming the Lagrangian, we have
11
Profit Maximizing

The F.O.C.s are
12
Profit Maximizing


As developed in Chapter 12, MR = p + (p/q)q
If there is perfect competition in output market,
p/q = 0 and MR = p
 Otherwise, firm also has some monopoly power in its
output market, so MR > p

First F.O.C. indicates that MR = *
 Substituting MR = * into next two F.O.C.s yields

conditions for profit maximization
• MICL = MRPL and MICK = MRPK
As defined in Chapter 16, MR(MPL) = MRPL, marginal
revenue product of labor
• Similarly, MR(MPK) = MRPK, marginal revenue product of capital
13
Profit Maximizing


As indicated in Figure 17.2, F.O.C.s imply that a monopsony has restricted labor
and decreased wages compared with perfectly competitive market solution
Monopsony firm equates MICL to MRPL for determining profit-maximizing level of
labor, LM
 Obtain wage rate necessary to acquire this level of labor by moving up to AICL curve
and across

A perfectly competitive market equilibrium corresponds to where AICL = MRPL
 Competitive-equilibrium input price and level of input are wC and LC, respectively
• Compared with a monopsony, LC > LM and wC > wM


To keep profits up, a monopsony will keep wages down
In case of monopsony power, MRPL curve is not labor demand curve of the firm
 As illustrated in Figure 17.2, if MRPL curve were the demand curve, at wM monopsony
would be willing to hire L' workers, but instead it is only willing to hire LM
• A monopoly restricts output and increases output price
• A monopsony restricts input and decreases input price
14
Figure 17.2 Comparison of perfect competition and
monopsony wage rate and labor employment
15
Inefficient Monopsony Market

Monopsony’s profit-maximizing solution is to restrict number
of workers and decrease wage rate compared with perfectly
competitive market solution
 Results in an inefficient solution where w = AICL < MRPL
• MRP is additional revenue or benefit to society from hiring an additional
•
worker
w is cost of hiring this additional worker
 Benefits are greater than cost, so society would prefer firm to
increase employment


In contrast, perfectly competitive solution is w = MRPL
 Additional benefits just equal additional cost
Can illustrate this inefficiency in a monopsony market by net
loss in consumer surplus and economic rent
16
Inefficient Monopsony Market

In a perfectly competitive input market, sum of consumer
surplus and economic rent is maximized

F.O.C. results in MRPL = AICL
 A perfectly competitive input market will result in MICL = AICL = MRPL
• Maximizes sum of consumer surplus and economic rent
17
Inefficient Monopsony Market



Inefficiency is illustrated in Figure 17.2
Under perfect competition, consumer surplus is area wCAB and economic rent is area
EwCB
A monopsony restricts amount of input employed
 Results in input price falling to wM
 Consumer surplus increases to area wMACD, which captures some of the perfect-competition
economic rent, area wMwCFD
• Measure of level of exploitation by monopsony



Efficiency loss resulting from monopsony power is represented by deadweight loss
 Shaded area DCB
In markets where firms are exploiting labor by exercising a great deal of monopsony power
 Poverty is not caused as a result of national resource scarcity but the rich exploiting the poor
A firm with monopsony power in its input market reacts much the same as a firm with
monopoly power in its output market
 In both cases, firm has control over its market
• By reacting to either consumer demand for a monopoly or input supply for a monopsony

Both types of firms restrict market allocation compared with perfectly competitive solution
18
Lerner Index

As with monopoly power, a Lerner Index exists for measuring degree of
monopsony power
 Measures relative wedge between wages, w, and MRPL

Specifically, given
 MICL = w[1 + (1/S)]
• At optimal level of profits

MRPL = w[1 +(1/S)]
 Solving for 1/S yields a Lerner Index
• LI(MRPL – w)/w = 1/S


Difference between MRPL and w provides a measure of monopsony power
Specifically, it is percentage markdown due to monopsony power
 If there are few alternatives for employment, supply curve for a firm becomes
more inelastic
• Wedge between MRPL and w increases, and LI increases, indicating a greater
degree of monopsony power
19
Lerner Index



Monopsony power is particularly prevalent where cost for workers to
relocate or commute for alternative employment is high
As these costs are reduced, monopsony power of firms declines
For example, first the automobile and then the interstate highway
system greatly increased mobility of workers
 Removing monopsony power of many company towns


Regional public transit systems that allow inner-city workers to be
employed outside the city decrease inner-city monopsony power of firms
Internet is currently greatly reducing monopsony power of many firms
 By giving many people ability to work from home and thus enlarging
employment opportunities
20
Table 17.1 Marginal Revenue Product,
Salaries, and Lerner Index for …
21
Monopoly in the Supply of Inputs

Suppliers of an input may form a cartel and exercise some degree of
monopoly power
 Objective of this type of cartel will vary, depending on nature of input

For example, labor unions may be more interested in
 Maximizing wages of current union membership or
 Increasing size of union
• Rather than maximizing union’s economic rent (equating marginal cost to
marginal revenue)


Generally assumed that a sole supplier of an input (other than labor) will
attempt to maximize economic rent (profit)
Supplier’s output is an input used by another firm
 Monopoly models for output and price determination discussed in Chapters
12 and 13 are applicable
22
Monopoly in the Supply of Inputs

A monopoly will generally restrict output below and increase price above
perfectly competitive equilibrium
 This same monopoly solution for a firm with monopoly power in the input
market is illustrated in Figure 17.3

Input monopoly is facing market demand for its output
 Horizontal summation of all firms’ derived demand for output supplied by this




monopoly
For a given SMC curve, input monopoly will equate SMC to MR associated
with this market demand and determine its profit-maximizing output, X*
Firm will then determine price, v*, at which it can sell all of this output from
market demand curve
Input monopoly can practice price discrimination and any other (legal?)
practices in an effort to enhance profit
Similarly, if there are a number of suppliers of an input, various gametheory models may describe their strategic interactions
23
Figure 17.3 Monopoly in the input
market
24
Bilateral Monopoly and
Bargaining

In 1981, after Professional Air Traffic Controllers Organization (PATCO)
went on strike, President Reagan fired 11,000 controllers
 It was not until August 1993 that President Clinton signed an executive order
lifting ban on rehiring of those controllers

• By 2002 only 800 of those controllers had been rehired
Scenario is an example of a bilateral monopoly
 A monopoly supplier of an input (traffic controllers) sells its input (labor) to a
monopsony buyer (FAA)
• A bilateral oligopoly, where a set of oligopoly firms supply to oligopsony firms can
also exist

Other examples of bilateral monopoly power are
 NFL players and owners
 U.S. Postal Service and National Postal Handlers Union
 A textile firm and Union of Needletrades, Industrial, and Textile Employees
(UNITE)
25
Bilateral Monopoly and
Bargaining
A bureau and its government review group
may be considered a bilateral monopoly
 A bureau is defined as
 A nonprofit organization that is financed by a

periodic appropriation
• Employees do not appropriate any part of the
difference between revenues and costs as personal
income
 Bureau sells its service only to government
• Government buys this service only from bureau
26
Bilateral Monopoly and
Bargaining

Case of a bilateral monopoly for an input, X, is illustrated in
Figure 17.4
 Curve labeled XD is either VMPX or MRPX curve
• According to whether final output produced by this input is sold under
conditions of perfect competition or monopoly
 MRPX curve represents how much monopsony is willing to pay per
unit for a given level of input
• Directly corresponds to AR curve for monopoly


Monopsony’s MRPX curve is monopoly’s AR curve
Although a monopoly has no supply curve, if a monopoly were constrained
to sell at competitive prices
 Upward-sloping portion of monopoly’s SMC curve above its SAVC
would indicate amounts that would be supplied
 SMC curve then represents how much monopoly is willing to supply at
a given wage
 Directly corresponds to AICX curve for monopsony
27
Figure 17.4 Bilateral monopoly
28
Bilateral Monopoly and
Bargaining


Monopsony solution is XM and vM
 Monopsony equates MRPX to MICX
Ignoring monopsony power of buyer and considering only monopoly power of seller
 Monopoly’s profit-maximizing output and price are XU and vU


• Monopoly equates MR to SMC
Buyer and seller are in general close to agreement on amount of input to hire
Objective of both is to restrict output from perfectly competitive solution
• Equilibrium level of input is often the same or close



Indicated in Figure 17.4
For example, professional football players are in general agreement with team owners on
number of players for each team
 However, there is an inherent conflict on wage rate
 Input price offered by monopoly, vU, is considerably higher than price offered by monopsony, vM
Given only one buyer and one seller of input, they will reach some agreement
 Impossible to determine actual price that will be established without knowing bargaining strengths
and skills of each firm
• We could only make assumptions and incorporate them into a game-theory model to determine optimal
strategies for agents
29
Bilateral Monopoly and
Bargaining

Recent bargaining situations between labor and management have
produced mixed results
 For example, bargaining in 1990s between Caterpillar and United Auto




Workers Union, along with 6- and 17-month strikes, resulted in very limited
gains by union
Now-famous bargaining phase between President Reagan and PATCO
resulted in controllers losing not only all their demands but also their jobs
In contrast, United Parcel Service (UPS) and Teamsters Union negotiations
(strike in 1996) resulted in more full-time employees
Numerous negotiations between baseball players’ union and team owners (8
strikes in 12 years) have diminished popularity of sport
• Potentially long-term damage to both players and owners
In general, monopsony buying power may be partially or entirely
negated by countervailing monopoly selling power
30
Labor Unions


A labor union is a cartel of workers with objective
of promoting interests of the union membership
Objective of a union varies a great deal depending
on desires of the membership or union bosses
 Some unions are solely interested in improving working

conditions and benefits of their members
Others may have social goals or a political agenda
• In the past, unions have advocated establishment of a communist
or socialist state
• However, most unions within U.S. are mainly interested in
improving members’ benefits
31
Unions’ Influence Over Wages

A labor union does not try to maximize wages
 Then only a few workers would be hired

It also does not encourage firms to hire as many workers as possible
 Because wage rate would be very low or zero

Instead, a general objective of a labor union may be to increase wages of union
members
 Wages are determined by forces of supply and demand
• Thus, for a union to modify wages it must in some way modify or change market for labor

Three general methods by which this can be done
 Increase demand for labor
• Probably most desirable method because it results in more workers being hired at an
increased wage
• However, most difficult method because in general unions have little influence over demand
for labor


One way unions attempt to increase labor demand is to increase demand for final product
 For example, union advertising encourages consumers to buy union-made products
In recent years, unions have supported laws for protective tariffs or quotas on imports and have
lobbied against free trade agreements
 However, limiting imports has effect of limiting exports, which can curtail labor employment
32
Unions’ Influence Over Wages

Increasing productivity of labor will also increase demand for labor
 To increase labor productivity, unions promote

• Improved working conditions
• Shortened work weeks
• Employee education
Negotiating over job descriptions may also increase or at least maintain
demand for labor
 May lead to featherbedding
• Attempt by unions to create or maintain jobs that employers claim are not really
necessary

Such make-work schemes are not very successful because they result
in unnecessary production costs
 High costs may in long-run result in higher output prices
• Lead to consumers finding substitute commodities
• Result in a decline in demand for union labor
33
Unions’ Influence Over Wages

A second method for increasing wages is to reduce supply of labor
 Unions are generally more successful with this method
• Particularly true among craft unions representing skilled trades
 Skilled unions can control supply by controlling entry into training or
apprenticeship program
• Requiring that employees have a certificate or license bearing witness of
•
successful completion of program
Power to license is generally in hands of union


Giving them power to restrict labor supply
Reducing supply of labor has effect of shifting supply curve for labor to
the left of what it would be with free entry
 Increases union wages and reduces number of workers employed
• Trade unions and professional associations have utilized this technique with a
high degree of success


Because reduced number of workers does not, at least in short-run, harm established
members
However, individuals who could obtain higher incomes if they were allowed to enter
union are harmed
 Consumers are harmed by paying more for services rendered
34
Unions’ Influence Over Wages

Third method is bargaining for higher wages
 Generally utilized by unskilled or semiskilled workers


• Including teamsters, steel workers, and auto workers
Goal is to bring all workers in industry into union membership
Semiskilled and unskilled unions are unable to restrict supply of workers
by licensing
 Differs from way skilled unions use licensing

Instead, semiskilled and unskilled unions will attempt to establish a
closed shop
 Where all workers in a firm or even industry must belong to union
 Union then represents all workers and negotiates with management
• It is important for union to require that all workers join union

Otherwise a worker could be an interloper
 Not join, save any union dues, and still reap any benefits from union negotiation
35
Unions’ Objectives

Consider a monopsony buyer of labor services confronting a large number of independent
sellers of these services
 In Figure 17.5, this results in equilibrium level of labor, LM, and wage, wM



Now, let a union organize and become sole supplier of labor services to monopsonist (the
Wobblies)
If union is powerful enough to enforce any wage rate it establishes and if objective of the
union is to maximize its economic rent
 Will seek a wage rate of w1 at an employment level of L1
However, union may have other objectives
 For example, union may prefer to obtain highest possible wage rate consistent with initial level of

employment LM, w2
Alternatively, union may seek largest wage bill (total revenue for union)
• Maximizing wage bill corresponds to where MR = 0, so union would offer L3 workers at a wage rate of w3
• However, at these wages (w2, w1, w3) an excess supply of labor exists


More workers are willing to supply their labor than the available demand
• Thus, for union to obtain these higher wages it must restrict supply of labor
In contrast, this excess supply of workers vanishes if union’s interests are to employ highest level
of laborers at a wage above wM
• Results in perfectly competitive solution of Le workers at a wage rate of we
36
Figure 17.5 Labor union’s
objectives
37
Unions’ Objectives

As illustrated in Figure 17.5, introduction of a labor union into a
previously monopsonized labor market
 May possibly result in a higher level of employment as well as in a higher
wage rate

For example, if a union is successful at increasing wage above
monopsony wage of wM, say wU in Figure 17.6
 Firm can hire all the labor it wants at this wage up to LU
 AICL is horizontal along this level of labor, so MICL is equal to it
 At LU, AICL is kinked and MICL curve shifts up to its previous level
• Thus, in short-run, firm will hire LU workers

Which is greater than LM
• And offer a wage wU

Which is higher than monopsony wage, wM
 Short-run result is a win/win situation for union
 It got firm to not only offer a higher wage but also be willing to hire more workers
38
Figure 17.6 Labor union’s wage
and employment
39
Long-Run Consequences

Eighty movies were shot in Boston, Massachusetts, from 1995 to 2000
 But in following two years only 15 films were made there

In spring of 2000, following complaints from studios that union had forced them
to hire more crew members than needed in exchange for labor peace during
filming
 Federal investigation found that union movie contracts from Boston Teamsters Local

25 had guaranteed union members 25 hours of overtime each week
Thus in recent years, location managers have shifted a significant amount of
production away from Boston area
• To less expensive countries such as Canada, Australia, and New Zealand, and to Pittsburgh,
Toronto, etc.

Example illustrates that in long-run unions may not be able to maintain higher
wages and higher levels of employment
 Firm’s cost curves will shift upward
• If upward pressure on costs results in increased prices, consumers might substitute other
commodities for firm’s output

Shifts firm’s demand curve for its output and inputs downward
 Result will be downward pressure on wages and labor layoffs
40
Long-Run Consequences


An example is long-run adjustment of U.S. auto industry in 1970s
Large wage hikes in 1970s, not generally associated with increased productivity
 Pushed up prices of U.S. automobiles to a point where they were no longer
competitive with foreign manufacturers
• Resulted in households substituting foreign cars for American cars


Caused high levels of unemployment among U.S. auto workers
Firms may attempt to mitigate this higher cost by seeking other regions for their
manufacturing operations with lower, nonunion labor costs
 Results in a loss of union employment and a reduction in wages

A current trend is for U.S. manufacturers to relocate just across Mexican border
 Labor costs and environmental restrictions are relatively low

Long-run consequences indicate that having a union card is no guarantee of
long-run relatively high wages
 If you are among early members of a union that was successful in raising wages, you
may benefit; however, encourage your children to go to college
• These relatively high-paying union jobs may not last into next generation of workers
41
Labor Strikes


A major tool unions have in labor negotiations is threat of striking
Labor strikes can take a number of forms
 From actual walking out and picketing to a worker slowdown, lasting for
years or only a few minutes

In all cases, a major objective of strikes is to show management how
union can and will cause a significant loss in a firm’s revenue
 However, it is not in the general interest of union to bankrupt a firm


A union must have ability to severely curtail output to have the power to
inflict damaging losses upon management and shareholders
Generally, in oligopolistic industries with a few large factories producing
a large share of a firm’s output
 By picketing limited entry and exit locations, strikers can shut down a factory
• And prevent nonstriking workers from crossing picket lines
 Thus, a strike or its threat can be a very effective tool in labor negotiations
42
Labor Strikes

However, in a perfectly competitive industry, such as
agriculture
 Where a relatively large number of firms produce in a large number
of open fields
• Effectiveness of strikes as a tool for labor negotiation is severely limited
 A union would probably not have resources to prevent production in
all the fields
• Could possibly only restrict industry output rather than shut it down

Specifically, in agricultural sector, migrant farm workers
have organized into a union
 Have attempted to use strikes as a tool for increasing wages
• Demand for migrant farm workers only exists during harvest

So migrant farm workers have attempted to increase wages by striking at
harvest
43
Labor Strikes

Goal of a strike is to significantly reduce production to point
where firms are operating at a loss
 However, as previously stated, it is difficult to prevent all farms from
harvesting their output with substitute labor
• Generally not possible for strikers to accomplish this goal
 In fact, a situation may result where union’s actions reduce supply of
output to point that market price, along with profits for firms,
increases
• In this case, union has forced firms into a cartel situation where they
earn pure profits

Thus, instead of forcing firms to increase wages so workers will come back
to work
 Union has provided incentives for firms to not agree with union
demands
44
Labor Strikes

This occurred when United Farm Workers in California went on strike in 1979
against California lettuce growers
 Studies indicate that lettuce growers, in general, did actually benefit from strike
 As a result of limited success of their strikes, United Farm Workers instead attempted
to increase wages by shifting demand curve for lettuce outward
• For example, they created a union label and encouraged restaurants and households to only
purchase union-labeled lettuce

A union often does have other objectives besides increasing wages in short run
 For example, a strike can provide a great deal of public exposure to problems facing
workers
• Could result in government policies addressing these problems

For example, National Association for Advancement of Colored People
supported Montgomery Bus Boycott lead by Martin Luther King, Jr. , from 1955
to 1956 along with various subsequent marches
 Resulted in landmark 1964 Civil Rights Act and 1965 Voting Rights Act
45