Transcript p(y)
25
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
Monopoly Behavior
How Should a Monopoly Price?
So
far a monopoly has been thought
of as a firm which has to sell its
product at the same price to every
customer. This is uniform pricing.
Can price-discrimination earn a
monopoly higher profits?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
2
Types of Price Discrimination
1st-degree:
Each output unit is sold
at a different price. Prices may differ
across buyers.
2nd-degree: The price paid by a
buyer can vary with the quantity
demanded by the buyer. But all
customers face the same price
schedule. E.g., bulk-buying
discounts.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
3
Types of Price Discrimination
3rd-degree:
Price paid by buyers in a
given group is the same for all units
purchased. But price may differ
across buyer groups.
E.g., senior citizen and student
discounts vs. no discounts for
middle-aged persons.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
4
First-degree Price Discrimination
Each
output unit is sold at a different
price. Price may differ across buyers.
It requires that the monopolist can
discover the buyer with the highest
valuation of its product, the buyer with
the next highest valuation, and so on.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
5
First-degree Price Discrimination
$/output unit
Sell the y th unit for $p( y ).
p( y )
MC(y)
p(y)
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
6
First-degree Price Discrimination
$/output unit
p( y )
Sell the y th unit for $p( y ). Later on
sell the y th unit for $ p( y ).
p( y )
MC(y)
p(y)
y
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
7
First-degree Price Discrimination
$/output unit
p( y )
p( y )
Sell the y th unit for $p( y ). Later on
sell the y th unit for $ p( y ). Finally
sell the y th unit for marginal
cost, $ p( y ).
MC(y)
p( y )
p(y)
y
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
y
8
First-degree Price Discrimination
The gains to the monopolist
on these trades are:
p( y ) MC( y ), p( y ) MC( y )
and zero.
$/output unit
p( y )
p( y )
MC(y)
p( y )
p(y)
y
y
y
y
The consumers’ gains are zero.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
9
First-degree Price Discrimination
$/output unit
So the sum of the gains to
the monopolist on all
trades is the maximum
possible total gains-to-trade.
PS
MC(y)
p(y)
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
10
First-degree Price Discrimination
$/output unit
The monopolist gets
the maximum possible
gains from trade.
PS
MC(y)
p(y)
y
y
First-degree price discrimination
is Pareto-efficient.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
11
First-degree Price Discrimination
First-degree
price discrimination
gives a monopolist all of the possible
gains-to-trade, leaves the buyers
with zero surplus, and supplies the
efficient amount of output.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
12
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
Price
paid by buyers in a given group
is the same for all units purchased.
But price may differ across buyer
groups.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
13
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
A
monopolist manipulates market
price by altering the quantity of
product supplied to that market.
So the question “What discriminatory
prices will the monopolist set, one for
each group?” is really the question
“How many units of product will the
monopolist supply to each group?”
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
14
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
Two
markets, 1 and 2.
y1 is the quantity supplied to market 1.
Market 1’s inverse demand function is
p1(y1).
y2 is the quantity supplied to market 2.
Market 2’s inverse demand function is
p2(y2).
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
15
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
For
given supply levels y1 and y2 the
firm’s profit is
( y1 , y2 ) p1 ( y1 )y1 p2 ( y2 )y2 c( y1 y2 ).
What
values of y1 and y2 maximize
profit?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
16
( y1 , y2
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
) p ( y ) y p ( y ) y c( y
1
1
1
2
2
2
1 y2 ).
The profit-maximization conditions are
c( y1 y2 ) ( y1 y2 )
p1 ( y1 )y1
y1 y1
( y1 y2 )
y1
0
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
17
( y1 , y2
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
) p ( y ) y p ( y ) y c( y
1
1
1
2
2
2
1 y2 ).
The profit-maximization conditions are
c( y1 y2 ) ( y1 y2 )
p1 ( y1 )y1
y1 y1
( y1 y2 )
y1
0
c( y1 y2 ) ( y1 y2 )
p 2 ( y2 )y2
y2 y2
( y1 y2 )
y2
0
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
18
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
y )
(y y )
( y1
2 1
and
y1
1
y2
2 1
so
the profit-maximization conditions are
c( y1 y2 )
p1 ( y1 )y1
y1
( y1 y2 )
c( y1 y2 )
and
.
p 2 ( y2 )y2
y2
( y1 y2 )
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
19
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
c( y1 y2 )
p1 ( y1 )y1
p 2 ( y2 ) y2
y1
y2
( y1 y2 )
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
20
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
c( y1 y2 )
p1 ( y1 )y1
p 2 ( y2 ) y2
y1
y2
( y1 y2 )
MR1(y1) = MR2(y2) says that the allocation
y1, y2 maximizes the revenue from selling
y1 + y2 output units.
E.g., if MR1(y1) > MR2(y2) then an output unit
should be moved from market 2 to market 1
to increase total revenue.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
21
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
c( y1 y2 )
p1 ( y1 )y1
p 2 ( y2 ) y2
y1
y2
( y1 y2 )
The marginal revenue common to both
markets equals the marginal production
cost if profit is to be maximized.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
22
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
Market 1
Market 2
p1(y1)
p1(y1*)
p2(y2)
p2(y2*)
MC
y1
y1*
MR1(y1)
MC
y2*
y2
MR2(y2)
MR1(y1*) = MR2(y2*) = MC
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
23
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
Market 1
Market 2
p1(y1)
p1(y1*)
p2(y2)
p2(y2*)
MC
y1
y1*
MR1(y1)
MC
y2*
y2
MR2(y2)
MR1(y1*) = MR2(y2*) = MC and p1(y1*) p2(y2*).
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
24
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
In
which market will the monopolist
cause the higher price?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
25
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
In
which market will the monopolist
cause the higher price?
Recall that
1
and
MR1 ( y1 ) p1 ( y1 ) 1
1
1
MR 2 ( y2 ) p2 ( y2 ) 1 .
2
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
26
Third-degree Price
Discrimination
In
which market will the monopolist
cause the higher price?
Recall that
1
and
But,
MR1 ( y1 ) p1 ( y1 ) 1
1
1
MR 2 ( y2 ) p2 ( y2 ) 1 .
2
MR1 ( y*1 ) MR 2 ( y*2 ) MC( y*1 y*2 )
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
27
So
p1
Third-degree Price
1
1
* Discrimination
*
(y ) 1
p (y ) 1
.
1
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
1
2
2
2
28
So
p1
Third-degree Price
1
1
* Discrimination
*
(y ) 1
p (y ) 1
.
1
1
2
2
2
Therefore, p1 ( y*1 ) p2 ( y*2 ) if and only if
1
1
1
1
1
2
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
29
So
p1
Third-degree Price
1
1
* Discrimination
*
(y ) 1
p (y ) 1
.
1
1
2
2
2
Therefore, p1 ( y*1 ) p2 ( y*2 ) if and only if
1
1
1
1
1
2
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
1 2 .
30
So
p1
Third-degree Price
1
1
* Discrimination
*
(y ) 1
p (y ) 1
.
1
1
2
2
2
Therefore, p1 ( y*1 ) p2 ( y*2 ) if and only if
1
1
1
1
1
2
1 2 .
The monopolist sets the higher price in
the market where demand is least
own-price elastic.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
31
Two-Part Tariffs
A
two-part tariff is a lump-sum fee,
p1, plus a price p2 for each unit of
product purchased.
Thus the cost of buying x units of
product is
p1 + p2x.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
32
Two-Part Tariffs
Should
a monopolist prefer a twopart tariff to uniform pricing, or to
any of the price-discrimination
schemes discussed so far?
If so, how should the monopolist
design its two-part tariff?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
33
Two-Part Tariffs
p1 + p2x
Q: What is the largest that p1 can be?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
34
Two-Part Tariffs
p1 + p2x
Q: What is the largest that p1 can be?
A: p1 is the “market entrance fee” so
the largest it can be is the surplus
the buyer gains from entering the
market.
Set p1 = CS and now ask what
should be p2?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
35
Two-Part Tariffs
$/output unit
Should the monopolist
set p2 above MC?
p(y)
p2 p( y)
MC(y)
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
36
Two-Part Tariffs
$/output unit
Should the monopolist
set p2 above MC?
p1 = CS.
p(y)
CS
p2 p( y)
MC(y)
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
37
Two-Part Tariffs
$/output unit
Should the monopolist
set p2 above MC?
p1 = CS.
PS is profit from sales.
p(y)
CS
p2 p( y)
PS
MC(y)
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
38
Two-Part Tariffs
$/output unit
Should the monopolist
set p2 above MC?
p1 = CS.
PS is profit from sales.
p(y)
CS
p2 p( y)
PS
MC(y)
Total profit
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
39
Two-Part Tariffs
$/output unit
p(y)
Should the monopolist
set p2 = MC?
MC(y)
p2 p( y)
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
40
Two-Part Tariffs
$/output unit
p(y)
p2 p( y)
Should the monopolist
set p2 = MC?
p1 = CS.
CS
MC(y)
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
41
Two-Part Tariffs
$/output unit
p(y)
CS
Should the monopolist
set p2 = MC?
p1 = CS.
PS is profit from sales.
MC(y)
p2 p( y) PS
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
42
Two-Part Tariffs
$/output unit
p(y)
CS
Should the monopolist
set p2 = MC?
p1 = CS.
PS is profit from sales.
MC(y)
p2 p( y) PS
Total profit
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
43
Two-Part Tariffs
$/output unit
p(y)
CS
Should the monopolist
set p2 = MC?
p1 = CS.
PS is profit from sales.
MC(y)
p2 p( y) PS
y
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
y
44
Two-Part Tariffs
$/output unit
p(y)
CS
Should the monopolist
set p2 = MC?
p1 = CS.
PS is profit from sales.
MC(y)
p2 p( y) PS
y
y
Additional profit from setting p2 = MC.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
45
Two-Part Tariffs
The
monopolist maximizes its profit
when using a two-part tariff by
setting its per unit price p2 at
marginal cost and setting its lumpsum fee p1 equal to Consumers’
Surplus.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
46
Two-Part Tariffs
A
profit-maximizing two-part tariff
gives an efficient market outcome in
which the monopolist obtains as
profit the total of all gains-to-trade.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
47
Differentiating Products
In
many markets the commodities
traded are very close, but not perfect,
substitutes.
E.g., the markets for T-shirts,
watches, cars, and cookies.
Each individual supplier thus has
some slight “monopoly power.”
What does an equilibrium look like
for such a market?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
48
Differentiating Products
entry zero profits for each
seller.
Free
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
49
Differentiating Products
entry zero profits for each
seller.
Profit-maximization MR = MC for
each seller.
Free
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
50
Differentiating Products
entry zero profits for each
seller.
Profit-maximization MR = MC for
each seller.
Less than perfect substitution
between commodities slight
downward slope for the demand
curve for each commodity.
Free
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
51
Price
Differentiating Products
Slight downward slope
Demand
Quantity
Supplied
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
52
Price
Differentiating Products
Demand
Quantity
Supplied
Marginal
Revenue
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
53
Price
Differentiating Products
Marginal
Cost
Demand
Quantity
Supplied
Marginal
Revenue
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
54
Price
Differentiating Products
Profit-maximization
MR = MC
Marginal
Cost
p(y*)
Demand
y*
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
Quantity
Supplied
Marginal
Revenue
55
Price
Differentiating Products
Zero profit
Price = Av. Cost
Profit-maximization
MR = MC
Average
Cost
Demand
p(y*)
y*
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
Marginal
Cost
Quantity
Supplied
Marginal
Revenue
56
Differentiating Products
Such
markets are monopolistically
competitive.
Are these markets efficient?
No, because for each commodity the
equilibrium price p(y*) > MC(y*).
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
57
Price
Differentiating Products
Zero profit
Price = Av. Cost
Profit-maximization
MR = MC
Marginal
Cost
Average
Cost
Demand
p(y*)
MC(y*)
y*
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
Quantity
Supplied
Marginal
Revenue
58
Price
Differentiating Products
Zero profit
Price = Av. Cost
Profit-maximization
MR = MC
Marginal
Cost
Average
Cost
Demand
p(y*)
MC(y*)
y*
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
ye
Quantity
Supplied
Marginal
Revenue
59
Differentiating Products
Each
seller supplies less than the
efficient quantity of its product.
Also, each seller supplies less than
the quantity that minimizes its
average cost and so, in this sense,
each supplier has “excess capacity.”
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
60
Price
Differentiating Products
Zero profit
Price = Av. Cost
Profit-maximization
MR = MC
Average
Cost
Demand
p(y*)
MC(y*)
Excess
capacity
y*
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
Marginal
Cost
ye
Quantity
Supplied
Marginal
Revenue
61
Differentiating Products by
Location
Think
a region in which consumers
are uniformly located along a line.
Each consumer prefers to travel a
shorter distance to a seller.
There are n ≥ 1 sellers.
Where would we expect these sellers
to choose their locations?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
62
Differentiating Products by
Location
0
1
x
If
n = 1 (monopoly) then the seller
maximizes its profit at x = ??
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
63
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
0
1
x
If
n = 1 (monopoly) then the seller
maximizes its profit at x = ½ and
minimizes the consumers’ travel
cost.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
64
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
0
1
x
If
n = 2 (duopoly) then the equilibrium
locations of the sellers, A and B, are
xA = ?? and xB = ??
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
65
A
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
0
B
1
x
If
n = 2 (duopoly) then the equilibrium
locations of the sellers, A and B, are
xA = ?? and xB = ??
How about xA = 0 and xB = 1; i.e. the
sellers separate themselves as much
as is possible?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
66
A
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
0
B
1
x
If
xA = 0 and xB = 1 then A sells to all
consumers in [0,½) and B sells to all
consumers in (½,1].
Given B’s location at xB = 1, can A
increase its profit?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
67
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
A
0
x’
B
1
x
If
xA = 0 and xB = 1 then A sells to all
consumers in [0,½) and B sells to all
consumers in (½,1].
Given B’s location at xB = 1, can A
increase its profit? What if A moves
to x’?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
68
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
A
0
x’
x
B
x’/2
1
If
xA = 0 and xB = 1 then A sells to all
consumers in [0,½) and B sells to all
consumers in (½,1].
Given B’s location at xB = 1, can A
increase its profit? What if A moves
to x’? Then A sells to all customers
in [0,½+½ x’) and increases its profit.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
69
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
A
0
x’
B
1
x
xA = x’, can B improve its profit
by moving from xB = 1?
Given
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
70
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
A
0
x’
x
x’’
B
1
xA = x’, can B improve its profit
by moving from xB = 1? What if B
moves to xB = x’’?
Given
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
71
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
A
0
x’
x
(1-x’’)/2
x’’
B
1
xA = x’, can B improve its profit
by moving from xB = 1? What if B
moves to xB = x’’? Then B sells to all
customers in ((x’+x’’)/2,1] and
increases its profit.
So what is the NE?
Given
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
72
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
0
x
A&B
1
xA = x’, can B improve its profit
by moving from xB = 1? What if B
moves to xB = x’’? Then B sells to all
customers in ((x’+x’’)/2,1] and
increases its profit.
So what is the NE? xA = xB = ½.
Given
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
73
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
0
x
A&B
1
The
only NE is xA = xB = ½.
Is the NE efficient?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
74
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
0
x
A&B
1
The
only NE is xA = xB = ½.
Is the NE efficient? No.
What is the efficient location of A and
B?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
75
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
¼
¾
0
A
x
B
1
The
only NE is xA = xB = ½.
Is the NE efficient? No.
What is the efficient location of A and
B? xA = ¼ and xB = ¾ since this
minimizes the consumers’ travel
costs.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
76
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
0
1
x
What
if n = 3; sellers A, B and C?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
77
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
0
1
x
What
if n = 3; sellers A, B and C?
Then there is no NE at all! Why?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
78
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
0
1
x
What if n = 3; sellers A, B and C?
Then there is no NE at all! Why?
The possibilities are:
– (i) All 3 sellers locate at the same point.
– (ii) 2 sellers locate at the same point.
– (iii) Every seller locates at a different
point.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
79
Differentiating Products by
Location
½
0
1
x
(iii)
Every seller locates at a different
point.
Cannot be a NE since, as for n = 2,
the two outside sellers get higher
profits by moving closer to the
middle seller.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
80
Differentiating Products by
½
Location
A
0
C
x
B
1
C gets 1/3 of the market
(i)
All 3 sellers locate at the same
point.
Cannot be an NE since it pays one of
the sellers to move just a little bit left
or right of the other two to get all of
the market on that side, instead of
having to share those customers.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
81
Differentiating Products by
½
Location
A B
0
x
C
1
C gets almost 1/2 of the market
(i)
All 3 sellers locate at the same
point.
Cannot be an NE since it pays one of
the sellers to move just a little bit left
or right of the other two to get all of
the market on that side, instead of
having to share those customers.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
82
Differentiating Products by
½
Location
A B
0
x
C
1
A gets about 1/4 of the market
2
sellers locate at the same point.
Cannot be an NE since it pays one of
the two sellers to move just a little
away from the other.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
83
Differentiating Products by
½
Location
A
0
x
B
C
1
A gets almost 1/2 of the market
2
sellers locate at the same point.
Cannot be an NE since it pays one of
the two sellers to move just a little
away from the other.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
84
Differentiating Products by
½
Location
A
0
x
B
C
1
A gets almost 1/2 of the market
2
sellers locate at the same point.
Cannot be an NE since it pays one of
the two sellers to move just a little
away from the other.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
85
If
Differentiating Products by
Location
n = 3 the possibilities are:
– (i) All 3 sellers locate at the same
point.
– (ii) 2 sellers locate at the same
point.
– (iii) Every seller locates at a
different point.
There is no NE for n = 3.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
86
If
Differentiating Products by
Location
n = 3 the possibilities are:
– (i) All 3 sellers locate at the same
point.
– (ii) 2 sellers locate at the same
point.
– (iii) Every seller locates at a
different point.
There is no NE for n = 3.
However, this is a NE for every n ≥ 4.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.
87