Tying and Foreclosure
Download
Report
Transcript Tying and Foreclosure
Tying and Foreclosure
Lecture Three
Daniel R. Vincent
Introduction:Monopoly Leverage
• In a number of the cases we described, a theory of harm
involved ‘monopoly leverage’.
• An incumbent was accused of exploiting its monopolized
market to foreclose competition in another market.
• Lepage’s v. 3M, Ortho v. Abbott, Smithkline v. Eli Lilly all
had this flavor.
• For example, in Lepage’s, 3M was accused of extorting
additional market share in the generic tape by granting
rebates on sales of its branded, Scotch Tape.
Introduction:Monopoly Leverage
• Recall that a common standard for finding a Section 2
violation is determining whether or not the action required
a “profit sacrifice”.
• In the case of monopoly leverage, some authors have
argued that anticompetitive foreclosure can arise in the
absence of a “sacrifice”.
• Nalebuff: “There is a second way that the firm with
market power in A can engage in costless foreclosure”.
• Greenlee, Reitman and Sibley (p. 8) “ Furthermore, since
the effect [of the discount on A] on profits is second-order
but that of [the rise in B} first order, firm 1’s profit
increases.”
Introduction:Monopoly Leverage
• If costless exclusion can arise, does this render the
standard pointless?
• In this lecture, I want to argue that the notion of costless
exclusion is a bit of a red herring.
• The strategies these authors identify is simply a natural
monopoly profit-seeking strategy that would arise whether
or not exclusion is possible.
• Since the practice would emerge with or without
exclusionary possibilities, it is hard to see why it would be
termed “exclusionary”
Introduction:Monopoly Leverage
• However, the practice leads us to a further question.
• These strategies can be shown to be dominated by much
better and less distortionary strategies.
• This fact leads us to ask, why are they used?
• The “No Economic Sense” test reemerges then since we
are now induced to investigate why an incumbent
monopolist intentionally chooses to employ a suboptimal
strategy.
Costless Exclusion
• Firm A is a secure monopolist over product 1.
• In product 2, it faces an actual or potential rival, firm B (or a
competitive fringe) capable of offering an identical product 2.
•
Demand for each product depends only on its own price.
• Firm A has constant marginal and average costs for both products,
(c1,c2).
• Firm B has marginal cost c2 and no fixed cost.
• These conditions imply that firm B is equally efficient as A, and they
rule out tying to monopolize market 2 since firm B can operate
efficiently at any small scale.
• A typical buyer’s demands for products 1 and 2 are linear.
p
1
1
Sm
p
2
p1m
m2
2
pm
p1xt
x1
1
c
m1
0
n
1
qm
e1
x2
2
p xt
c2
qe1
2
qm
0
Figure 1
qe2
e2
Interpretations of the Demand Curve
• Note that the simplest view of the demand curve is the
standard interpretation that it represents the buyer’s
willingness to pay for the good and, thus, the area under
the demand curve is CS.
• However, in standard cases, the downstream buyer is
another firm.
• Thus the demand curve is really a derived demand curve (a
retailer’s marginal revenue curve for example).
• Interpretations as CS are therefore suspect.
• We will proceed though as if area is CS.
Monopoly Linear Pricing Leaves Consumer
Surplus and Inefficiency
• The simple monopoly price-quantity point is m1 in market 1 and m2 in
market 2.
• These are the price-quantity pairs firm A would choose if it were an
unconstrained monopolist in both markets / products.
• If firm A faces perfect competition in 2 and cannot tie its products, it
stays at m1 but prices 2 at marginal cost, leading to the socially
efficient point in market 2,e2.
• In market 1, the monopoly price leaves consumer surplus equal to the
triangle S1m, and a “deadweight loss” triangle.
• If firm A could charge a fixed fee as well as a per-unit price, it would
cut price down to marginal cost , thereby expanding consumption and
eliminating the deadweight loss, and charge a fixed fee equal to the
consumer surplus realized at point .
Monopoly Linear Pricing Leaves Consumer
Surplus and Inefficiency
• However, given the assumed restriction to only per-unit prices, there is
a rent extraction role for tying.
• This can be shown for two alternative cases:
– firm A may offer a tied package, but must also offer product 1 at the
simple monopoly price, a practice Nalebuff [2004a] calls mixed tying;
– or it may engage in pure tying. In this case, it offers good 1 only at such a
high price that none would be purchased alone.
– Q: Is pure tying a sequentially credible strategy? What about two part
tariffs?
Mixed Tying
• Under mixed tying, the monopoly product must remain
available at the simple monopoly price.
• The consumer’s unbundled option is point m1 in market
1and point e2 in market 2.
• To be accepted, any tied offer must leave consumer surplus
of at least S1m + p2c2e2.
• Thus, firm A’s gain from adding a tied offer cannot come
from harming the buyer.
Mixed Tying
• Nevertheless, mixed tying can benefit firm A — by reducing the
deadweight loss on product 1.
• This is done by cutting its price somewhat below the monopoly level
while raising the price of 2 somewhat above marginal cost, and
requiring buyers to buy 2 at this higher price as a condition for
obtaining the lower price on 1.
• The deadweight loss will be reduced because starting at the efficient
point in market 2, a small rise in price and fall in quantity reduces
welfare W only negligibly
• But the quantity expansion in 1 increases W significantly.
• Since total welfare can be increased, there exists a pair of prices firm A
can charge that leave the same consumer surplus as the unbundled
option but yields higher profit.
Mixed Tying
• Geometrically, to maintain , the mixed tying prices are set
so that the consumer’s gain from the price cut on product 1
(trapezoid p1mm1x1p1xt in Figure 1) equals the loss from the
price rise on product 2 (trapezoid c2e2x2p2xt ). We return to
this property of the mixed-tying prices when discussing the
Ortho test.
•
Observe that this pricing pattern still leaves both quantities
below their efficient levels and, hence, is still inferior to
charging a fixed fee in market 1 and setting both prices at
marginal costs.
p
1
1
Sm
p
2
p1m
m2
2
pm
p1xt
x1
1
c
m1
0
n
1
qm
e1
x2
2
p xt
c2
qe1
2
qm
0
Figure 1
qe2
e2
Pure Tying
• Firm A may offer product 1 only tied with 2, or also unbundled but at a
price of its choosing.
• By raising the unbundled price of 1 to a prohibitive level ( or higher),
firm A can de facto adopt pure tying, and reduce the consumer surplus
under the unbundled option from to , the level available by buying
only product 2 competitively.
• Thus, pure tying removes the consumer surplus that was available
from buying product 1 unbundled at its monopoly price.
• Making the unbundled option less attractive lets firm 1 set the puretying prices above the mixed-tying levels discussed above.
Effect on Consumers and Overall
Welfare
• The pure tying prices are determined by the following alternative
conditions:
• (i) Unconstrained Monopoly: If the simple monopoly prices yield
consumer surplus of at least p2c2e2, then firm A will set its tied prices at
the simple monopoly levels in both markets: m1,m2.
• Costless exclusion in this case?
• (ii) Constrained Monopoly: If consumer surplus at m1,m2 is less than
p2c2e2, then firm will A set its pure tying prices below the monopoly
levels, but still higher than under mixed tying: (p1xt , p2xt) < (p1t , p2t) <
(p1m, p2m) .
• Case (i) arises, for example, if market 2 is small relative to 1, while (ii)
arises if market 2 is relatively large.
Effect on Consumers and Overall
Welfare
• The possible welfare effects of pure tying are as follows:
• Consumer Surplus under pure tying is lower than under no tying or
mixed tying. This result follows immediately because pure tying
raises the prices of both goods relative to mixed tying which, in turn,
yields the same consumer surplus as no tying ().
• Welfare under pure tying is lower than under mixed tying. This, too,
follows because pure tying raises prices above the mixed tying levels,
which already exceed marginal costs. Thus, consumption of both
goods is reduced further below the efficient levels.
Effect on Consumers and Overall
Welfare
• Welfare under pure tying can be lower or higher than under no tying.
–
Welfare is higher under pure tying if the prices are close to marginal
costs, as will occur if market 2 is large relative to 1. Tying then lets firm A
exploit its monopoly power relatively efficiently: it accepts a large price
reduction in the monopoly market in exchange for a positive but small
margin in the larger market 2. Figure 1 illustrates such a case.
– Welfare is lower under pure tying if market 2 is relatively small. The pure
tying prices then will be near, or equal to, the monopoly levels, so tying
reduces price only slightly if at all in market 1, but raises price in market
2 substantially above its no tying level of marginal cost.
Ortho and Related Tests
• Recall the notion of “compensatory pricing”
due to Ordover:
– Is the incremental revenue from selling the two additional tests greater
than the revenue forgone as a result of the price cuts of the original three
test? If so, then the package is deemed "compensatory", otherwise it is
viewed as a violation of Section 2
• We can pose this as
– [sum of all tied prices – sum of unbundled prices except 2] < (unit
cost of 2)
• The term in brackets is the implicit price of
good 2.
Ortho Tests
• In terms of the Figure, this can be posed as
– [p1xt+ p2xt- p1u]<c2
• or with some simple manipulation
– [p1xt+ p2xt- (c1+c2)]<(p1u- c1)
• Notice, if the unbundled price of 1 was set at average cost,
then the test just asks whether the bundle is priced at
average costs.
• Consider the case of mixed tying. Then p1u=p1m.
• The right side is independent of market 2.
Ortho Tests
• Consider the following simple special case:
– Demand in market 1:q=D1(p)=a-p
– Demand in market 2:q=D2(p)=sD1(p)
• Thus, s is a measure of the relative size of the markets.
• An implication is that, at the same price, the elasticities are
the same in each market.
• Let c1=c2=c, (equal marginal costs).
• Show the following “Ramsey” formula. The optimal
pricing for a monopolist required to yield consumer
surplus of u is given by (pj-c)/c=k(s)/Ej
• where k is a positive number depending on s.
Ortho Tests
• This result implies p1xt(s)=p2xt(s)=p(s) and the Ortho test
becomes
– 2(p(s)-c)<p1m-c
• Show that as s becomes large, p(s) approaches c. As s
becomes small, p(s) approaches p1m.
• The inequality can go either way depending on s.
• Thus, whether or not optimal pricing by the monopolist
violates the Ortho test depends solely on the relative size
of the markets.
Ortho Tests
• Recall that under mixed tying, total welfare always goes
up.
• Since by assumption, there is never an issue about
foreclosure, so the motive is pure rent extraction by the
monopolist.
• Still the Ortho test would find a violation whenever s is
large.
• Furthermore, the larger s is, the more likely to find a
violation, AND the more is the welfare enhancement of the
policy.
Ortho Tests
• Note that the source of both profitability and welfare gains
comes from quantity expansion from the fall in price in
market 1.
• If demand in 1 is inelastic, then, the tying policy cannot be
welfare enhancing nor can it be explained as a substitute
instrument for two part tariffs.
• Recall the trial court judge’s comment
•
"...the package pricing structure Abbott adopted cut the prices of all five
assays. As demand for a firm's products ordinarily is a function of pricelower prices generally mean greater demand-Abbott's CCBC pricing
reasonably may be expected to have increased its unit sales of all of the assays
and thereby to have generated added profits offsetting, at least in part, the
revenue loss attributable to the price cuts. Ordover's deposition testimony
does not confront this matter with any specificity. "
Ortho Test Does not Protect Equally Efficient
Competitors (‘Aquit the Guilty’).
• Note, that by assumption of the example, c2=c for Firms A
and B.
• Mixed or pure tying in this scenario would always lead
Firm A to “foreclose” B.
• But an Ortho test may NOT find a violation (if s is small in
the example).
• Thus, it cannot “protect” equally efficient competitors.
Ortho Test Does not Protect Equally Efficient
Competitors (‘Aquit the Guilty’).
• The Ortho Test may even fail to find a violation when Firm A engages
in pure tying and total welfare falls.
• Let the costs in the two markets be the same.
• Let demand be linear but vertical intercept in 1, p1* be lower than 2, p2*
and horizontal intercept be farther than 2.
• Pure tying can emerge with an unbundled price of p1* in 1.
• Suppose that the monopolist is unconstrained. Then tied prices are
(pi*+c)/2, i=1,2.
• The test is passed if (p2*-c)/2< (p1*-c)/2 which will generally be true.
• By varying the intercepts of market 1 holding market 2 fixed, the
environment can be constructed so that the monopolist is
unconstrained. Note that total welfare falls with the tie in this case.
What is the Motive for the Tie?
• In all the cases above, the motive for the tie would vanish
if Firm A could utilize two part tariffs in market 1.
• (Note that in that case, marginal prices in each market
would equal marginal costs, there are no efficiency gains
from the tie and therefore, no possibility of profitable
tying.)
• Thus, one view of the motive for tying is that it serves as
an imperfect substitute for nonlinear pricing.
• We allow firms to extract profits for legitimately acquired
monopoly, why not here? (It “Makes Economic Sense”?)
Or is it Sensible?
• But we need to look more closely at why nonlinear pricing
was infeasible.
• A tie-out is hard to implement. It requires monitoring all
purchases a buyer makes.
• What about a minimal tie-in. A buyer can get a particular
price for the monopoly good if it buys some minimal unit
of the tied good from A.
• The amount can be very small, so there is virtually no
distortion in market 2.
• The price can be very high, so it is as if it is the fixed part
of a two part tariff.
Or is it Sensible?
• Since a two part tariff is profit maximizing and appears to be
implementable whenever a tie-out is implementable, why is something
more than a minimal tie-in used?
• Does the “no economic sense” story re-emerge in this light?
• Mathewson and Winter (1997) offer an explanation in terms of
incomplete information. If A does not know the true demand of the
buyer for good 1 and if demands are statistically related, then the tieout could be an optimal way of screening different types of buyers.
• But, if this is the motive, is it anticompetitive?
• Why is a “tie” needed to achieve this goal?
Exclusion?
• The logic seems to lead us to the observation that
something more than a minimal tie is suspicious.
• If Firm A is choosing to use some policy that is other than
profit maximizing, why is it giving up this potential profit?
• Two questions in fact. Can it “buy” market power in a
market in equilibrium?
• If so, we note that money (profit) is fungible. Why might it
use profits from market 1 to buy this market power in 2?
• Partial and not very satisfactory answers exist for the
second question. We investigate the first in the next
lectures.