Calibrated Economic Models
Download
Report
Transcript Calibrated Economic Models
Quantitative Analysis
Of Competitive Effects
For Antitrust
Day 1
Luke Froeb
Owen Graduate School of Management
Vanderbilt University
April, 2003
Case Studies Showing How
Modeling is Used in Antitrust
WorldCom-Sprint
Consumer Branded Product
Carnival-Princess
WorldCom-Sprint Merger:
Background
Merger
scrutinized by
– U.S. Department of Justice
– Federal Communications Commission
– Interested third parties like Bell Atlantic
Overlap
in residential long distance service
Regulatory restrictions keeping local phone
companies out of market were soon to fall
WorldCom-Sprint Merger:
Methodology
Estimate consumer
choice model
(demand)
Estimate/Calibrate
Firm Model (supply)
Simulate “ownership”
effect of merger
Share
Price
World 16.5
Com
Sprint 6.9
16.5
AT&T 56.4
17.6
Others 20.1
14.4
17.9
WorldCom-Sprint Merger:
Simulated Merger Effects
Demand estimation from bill “harvesting”
– Inelastic demand
– Predicted price increases for merging firms
WorldCom: 5.4%
Sprint: 8.9%
Calibration from WorldCom’s margin
– Small margins imply more elastic demand
– Predicted price increases for merging firms
WorldCom: 2.2%
Sprint: 5.1%
WorldCom-Sprint Merger:
Mergers in a Post-Entry World
Does
entry occur in response to merger?
Entry by incumbent local exchange
carriers (“Baby Bells”)
– State-level “experiments” show 25% share
of long distance
– What is merger effect in post-entry world?
Baby
Bell entry cuts the industry average
price effect in half
Branded Consumer
Goods Merger
This
is a real case that must be kept
confidential, so numbers are disguised
Entrant
gained 25% share in two years
Proposed
Only
to purchase rival brand
3 brands in “high end” segment
Aggregate
segment elasticity 1.5
Branded Consumer Goods Merger:
Brand Elasticity, Prices, Shares
A-Price B-Price C-Price
Price Share
A-Quant.
2.21
0.44
0.28
$20
35%
B-Quant.
0.39
2.16
0.28
$20
40%
C-Quant.
0.39
0.44
2.32
$20
25%
Branded Consumer Goods Merger:
Findings
Estimated
demand implies brands are
fairly good substitutes for one another
Predicted industry price increase of 4%
Merging
and 8%
12%
brand price increases of 5%
and 18% marginal cost reductions
required to offset price increases
Is Merger Prediction Consistent
with Entry Experience?
Incumbent
brands did not reduce price
in response to entry with a 25% share
Implies entrant is bad substitute
Yet,
we get a significant price increase
following merger
Implies entrant is good substitute
Is
post-merger price increase consistent
with no incumbent entry response?
How to Answer Question
Calibrate
model to observed data
“Undo”
entry by raising price of recent
entrant until zero quantity
Compare
price changes of remaining
(incumbent) brands
Entry
effects are reverse of “undoing”
entry effects
Consumer Goods Merger:
Entry Model
Prices of incumbent
brands barely change
Quantity drops
significantly
Entrants steal
quantity, but do not
affect price
In general, other firms
do not much affect
price
A
B
ΔP -0.85% -0.95%
ΔQ -10.3% -9.98%
Consumer Goods Merger:
How Can We Test this Prediction?
Where
from?
did entrant’s quantity come
65% from “outside” option
Includes lower priced brands
35% from incumbent brands
Is
this consistent with entry data?
If not, may want to modify model
2002 Cruise Line Merger:
Introduction
Carnival (largest) and Royal Caribbean
(second-largest) each bid for Princess (thirdlargest)
Capacity constraints and “perishable” service
– big fixed costs, small marginal costs
Key strategy is “revenue management”
– Price to match uncertain demand to available
capacity, i.e. to “fill the ships”
Merger of Parking Lot Operators
Central Parking acquired Allright
Two largest parking lot operators in US
Pricing: “Is lot full by 9am?”
If “no,” then reduce price
If “yes,” then raise price
This profit calculus unchanged by merger
No merger effect if lots are full
But Justice Department opposed merger
Asked for 74 lot divestitures in 18 cities
Cruise Lines vs. Parking Lots
Similar strategies: filling ships vs. filling lots
There is no uncertainty about parking
demand, but does that make a difference?
Theories considered by FTC
Fill-the-ship pricing is unaffected by merger
No quantity effect, but low-elasticity consumers
pay more
Were theories correct? Magnitude of effects?
Conclusions Based on Formal Model
of Revenue Management
Two merger effects
– Ownership effect raises price
– Information-sharing effect raises or lowers price
But always increases quantity
Both effects small and disappear as
uncertainty decreases
Confirms basic intuition from parking lot
merger, i.e. firms price to fill the ships, and
this profit calculus is unchanged by merger
Spatial Competition
Grocery Store Merger
Parking Lot Merger
Geographic Differentiation
Retail Sector is Consolidating
In US, Wal-Mart, K-Mart, Target, Costco, and
Sears account for 60 percent of generalmerchandise sales
– General-merchandise is 15 % of all retail sales
Productivity advantage over smaller retailers
– Economies of scale
– Economies of purchasing
– Economies of distribution
Productivity Gains Associated with
Industry Consolidation
Retail Consolidation
Also in Europe
In
EU, top 10 grocery stores forecast to
increase share to 50-60%
– In 2002, top 10 had 38%
Wal-Mart entering
Europe
Policy Reaction to Retail
Consolidation
FTC
challenged some retail mergers
– Blocked Kroger + Winn-Dixie
– Blocked Staples + Office Depot
Competitive
analysis based on increase
in local (within-city) horizontal market
power
– “standard” horizontal analysis
Quantitative Horizontal Analysis:
Benefit-Cost Analysis of Merger
Goal:
effect
quantitative estimate of merger
– Necessary to weigh efficiencies against loss
of competition
Two
methodologies
– “Natural” experiments, e.g. Staples-Office
Depot
– Model-based simulations
Natural Experiments:
Staples-Office Depot
Prices in two-office-superstore cities found to
be 7% lower than in one-office-superstore city
– Is this a good metaphor for merger?
Pass-through rate (from cost to prices) was
estimated to be 15%
This implies that a 85% reduction in costs
necessary to offset merger effect
FTC successfully challenged merger
Model-Based Simulation
Model
current competition
Estimate model parameters
Simulate loss of competition using
estimated parameters
Unilateral competitive effect computed
as difference between pre- and postmerger Nash equilibria
Model-Based Simulation:
Kroger + Winn Dixie
Estimate “gravity”
choice model
– Survey density in
Charlotte, NC
– Dots represent
grocery stores
Choice depends on
price, distance, and
“noise”
Pre-Merger Equilibrium:
Share of Kroger + Winn-Dixie
Post-Merger Equilibrium:
Share of Kroger+Winn-Dixie
Parking Lot
Merger
“Gravity” choice
model
Lots derive
market power
from location,
capacity
Higher prices if
– Few nearby lots
– Many nearby
consumers
– Small lot capacity
Parking Lot Merger Model:
Conclusions
Constraints on merging lots attenuate merger
effects by more than constraints on nonmerging ones amplify them
Merger effects poorly approximated by
shares in geographic market areas
– No bright lines between “in” and “out”
– Shares poor proxies for localized competition
Justice Department erred when it asked for
divestitures in 5-square block areas where the
merging firms account for more than 35%
Gravity Choice Models
And Merger Effects
Merger effects “depend” on
– Location of consumers
– Location of merging stores
– Location of non-merging firms
– Cost of travel
– Other factors affecting demand
Weak
generalization: small price effects
if location only source of market power
Differentiated Products
What if we can’t estimate demand?
Modelling choices and trade-offs
Accounting for efficiencies
Model-Based Methodology
Specify
and estimate a model
– Consumer model (demand)
– Firm model (supply)
Use
model to simulate counterfactual
scenario
– Mergers, collusion, damages
Example and Questions
To “Test” Approach
Logit demand curve
– What about other forms?
Price-setting competition
– What about product, promotion, placement?
– What about auctions, quantity-setting, vertical
arrangements?
Constant marginal cost
– What about scale economies or capacity constraints?
Static game
– What about dynamic strategies?
Unilateral merger counterfactual
– What about coordinated effects?
Critique of Market Share Screens
With Differentiated Products
Competition does not stop at market
boundary
Shares may be poor proxies for
competitive effects
No role for efficiencies
How do you trade off a 10% marginal cost
reduction against a 400 point change in HHI?
Common Problem: Cannot Get
Reliable Demand Estimate
Relatively
flexible functional forms
often lead to nonsensical estimates
– Goods are complements (when we know
they are substitutes)
– Inelastic demand (inconsistent with
optimization)
Data
not up to task of estimating so
many parameters
Solution: Ask Less of Data by
Making Intuitive Assumptions
If one firm increases price, its rivals gain
quantity in proportion to existing shares
– Implies all goods are substitutes
– Implies margins proportional to shares
– Implies cross elasticities proportional to shares
These restrictive forms require less data
– Aggregate elasticity
– One brand level elasticity or margin
Swedish beer
merger
Aggregate
elasticity ≈ 1
Pripps margin ≈
30%
Significant
industry average
price increase
1.4
Aggregate Elasticity
Replacing
Market Share
Screens
4%
1.2
1
5%
0.8
0.6
6%
7%
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
Pripps 2.8% Demand Elasticity
Logit Model
as a Screen
WorldComSprint Merger
Aggregate
elasticity ≈ -1
WorldCom
Margin ≈ 30%
Relatively
small price
effects
Using Logit Model as Screen III
Rebuttable
presumption starts dialogue
– Show products are further apart than modeled
– Show competition is more intense than modeled
Requires
different safe harbors
– “Give” parties a 5% MC reduction on each of their
merging products
Would have allowed MCI-Sprint, but not beer
How Do you Incorporate
Merger-Specific Efficiencies?
How
much do cost savings affect postmerger equilibrium?
One product assumes the mc of the other; or
Parties “prove” merger-specific cost reductions
Compute
cost reductions sufficient to
offset predicted price increase
In general, 2X to 3X times computed
product price rise is enough.
Because pass-through related to postmerger price increase
Which Welfare Standard?
Total vs. Consumer Welfare
Do fixed costs count?
Superior Propane in Canada fixed cost
savings but prices went up.
Gain in profits was higher than consumer
welfare loss
Canada
is only country with a total
welfare standard.
Short-run price increases vs. long-run
efficiencies