Chapter 1: The Market - University of Minnesota
Download
Report
Transcript Chapter 1: The Market - University of Minnesota
Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical
Industrial Organization (NEIO)
modified from:
http://spirit.tau.ac.il/public/gandal/lecture11i.pdf
What is the old empirical IO?
The old empirical IO refers to studies that tried to draw
inferences about the relationship between the structure of an
industry (in particular, its concentration level) and its
profitability.
Problems with those studies are that
it is hard to measure profitability,
industry structure may be endogenous, and
there is little connection between empirical work and theory.
The NEIO is in many ways a reaction to that empirical tradition.
NEIO works “in harmony” with (game) theory.
The Structure-Conduct-Performance (SCP)
Paradigm: The Old Empirical IO
How does industry concentration affect
price-cost margins or other similar
measures?
The “plain vanilla” SCP regression
regresses profitability on concentration.
The Cournot model of non-cooperative
oligopolistic competition in homogeneous
product industries relates market structure
to performance.
It can be shown that shared weighted
average markup in an industry is a
function of its Herfindahl index and the
elasticity of demand.
p mci
i p si
where
HHI si2
i
HHI
This implies:
ln(PCM) = 0 + 1 ln(HHI) + 2 ln() +
(1)
where PCM = the share weighted average firm markup.
Using cross section data, (1) could be estimated and a test for
Cournot would be 0 = 0, 1 = 1, and 2 = -1.
In practice, regressions of the following form were performed:
ln(PCM) = 0 + 1 C4 +
(2)
where C4 was the share of the four largest firms in the
industry.
What are the problems with these regressions?
Data: Price cost margins are not available, hence accounting
returns on assets (as well as census data on manufacturer
margins) were often used.
Data: Additional RHS variables such as the elasticity of
demand are hard to measure for many industries.
Data: Market definitions were problematic. (When using a
single industry more thought can be put into the issue.)
Simultaneity: Both margins and concentration are
endogenous.
Demsetz (J. Law and Econ., 1973) noted that some firms have
a cost advantage, leading to a large share and high profits.
Hence, there could be a correlation between C4 and profits.
The New Empirical Industrial Organization
(NEIO) Paradigm: The New Empirical IO
The NEIO studies
build on the econometric progress made by SCP paradigm,
use economic theory,
describe techniques for estimating the degree of
competitiveness in an industry,
use bare bones prices and quantities, and do not rely on cost
or profit data,
typically assume that the firms are behaving as if they are
Bertrand competition,
use comparative statics of equilibria to draw inferences about
profits and costs, and
focus mainly on a single industry in order to deal better with
product heterogeneity, institutional details, etc.
Bresnahan (Economic Letters, 1982):
The Oligopoly Solution Concept is Identified
This paper and others (e.g., A. Nevo, “Identification of the Oligopoly Solution Concept in a
Differentiated Products Industry,” Economics Letters, 1998, 391-395) show that the oligopoly
solution concept can be identified econometrically.
Demand:
MC:
Q = 0 + 1 P + 2 Y
MC = 0 + 1 Q + 2 W
+
+
(1)
(2)
where Y and W are exogenous.
FOC for a PC firm:
FOC for a monopoly:
P/Q)
MC = P
( MR is: P)
MC = P + Q/1 ( MR is: P + Q *
FOC for the oligopolistic firm: MC = (1 - ) P + (P + Q/1)
where
= 0 if the industry is competitive
Demand:
(1)
MC:
(2)
FOC:
Q
=
0 + 1 P + 2 Y +
MC = 0 + 1 Q + 2 W +
MC = (1 - ) P + (P + Q/1)
Substituting FOC into (2), the supply relationship is:
(1 - ) P + (P + Q/1) = 0 + 1 Q + 2 W +
P = (- Q/1 ) + 1 Q + 0 + 2 W +
(3)
Since both (1) and (3) have one endogenous variable and since
there is one excluded exogenous variable from each equation,
both equations are identified. But, are we estimating P = MC
(competitive) or MR = MC (monopoly)?
Rewrite (3) as:
P = (1 - /1) Q + 0 + 2 W +
We can obtain a coefficient for (1 - /1) since (3) is identified
and we can get 1 by estimating (1).
In the figure, E1 could
either be an equilibrium for
a monopolist with marginal
cost MCM, or for a perfectly
competitive industry with
cost MCC.
MCC
Increase Y to shift the
demand curve out to D2
and both the monopolistic
and competitive equilibria
move to E2.
E2
E1
MCM
Unless we know marginal
costs, we cannot
distinguish between
competitive or monopoly
(nor anything in between).
MR1 MR2
D1
D2
The solution to the identification problem
MC:
MC = 0 + 1 Q + 2 W +
(2)
Let demand be:
Q = 0 + 1 P + 2 Y + 3 P Z + 4
Z+
where Z is another exogenous variable. The key is that Z enters
interactively with P, so that changes in P and Z both rotate and
vertically shift demand. (Note: Z might be the price of a substitute
good, which makes the interaction term intuitive.)
Given the new demand, the marginal revenue for a monopolist, (P
+ Q * P/Q), is no longer P + Q/1. It is now: P + Q / (1 + 3
Z).
Thus, the oligopolistic firm’s FOC becomes
MC = (1 - ) P + [P + Q / (1 + 3 Z)]
Substituting FOC into (2), the supply relationship becomes:
Demand:
Q
=
0 + 1 P + 2 Y + 3 P Z + 4 Z +
Supply Relation:
`
P
= - [Q / (1 + 3 Z)] + 1 Q + 0 + 2 W +
- Q*
+ 1 Q + 0 + 2 W +
Since the demand is still identified, we can estimate 1 and
3.
Thus, we can identify both and 1 in the supply relation.
Note 1: This result can be generalized beyond linear functions.
Note 2: There are other assumptions that can generate
identification.
e.g.
Marginal cost that does not vary with quantity (1 =
Graphically, an
exogenous change in
the price of the
substitute rotates the
demand curve around
E1.
If there is perfect
competition, this will
have no effect on the
equilibrium price and
it will stay at the point
associated with E1.
But, if there is
monopoly power, the
equilibrium will
change to E3.
MCC
E1
E2
MR1
MCM
MR2
D1
D2
Why do we care about the structural model?
We want to estimate parameters or effects not directly
observed in the data (e.g., returns to scale, elasticity of
demand).
We want to perform welfare analysis (e.g., measure
welfare gains due to entry or welfare losses due to
market power).
We want to simulate changes in the equilibrium (e.g.,
impact of mergers).
We want to compare relative predictive performance of
competing theories.