11 Markets and consumer demand

Download Report

Transcript 11 Markets and consumer demand

MIFIRA Framework
Lecture 11
Markets and consumer demand
Chris Barrett and Erin Lentz
February 2012
Households and Consumption: Analysis
of Demand
• Household consumption choices
–
–
–
–
–
–
Access: How do households interact with markets?
Preferences: Which transfer(s) do households prefer?
Terms of trade (ToT)
Elasticities
Marginal propensities to consume (MPC)
Commodities: Which commodities to analyze?
2
Q1. Are local markets functioning well?
• 1a. Are food insecure households well connected to local
markets?
• 1b. How will local demand respond to transfers?
• 1e. Do food insecure households have a preference over the
form/mix of aid they receive?
• 2b. Will agency purchases drive up food prices excessively
in source markets?
3
Access
• Basic info: which markets, for what products,
when?
• What constrains access?
– Community-level market access and inter-community
constraints
• Distance, safety, costs, seasons
– Intra-community constraints
• Socio-cultural reasons (gender, caste, marital status, etc.),
safety, OVCs, HIV+ households
• When are access constraints insurmountable?
4
Community-level access questions
• What types of markets can community members
access?
– Are any markets currently inaccessible?
– Does this vary with seasons?
• How far away are the markets?
– Can households travel to a larger market if local
market prices increase too much?
• Are there key products not locally produced
unavailable in the market?
– Does this appear to be due to commercial supply
disruptions, government trade bans, high prices,
insufficient local demand, or some other reason?
5
Intra-community market access
questions
• Does everyone within a community have equal
access to local markets?
– How does market access differ for likely targeted
recipients?
– How do households with limited access cope?
– Which household members use markets?
– Do households use cash, credit, or barter?
• What staples and substitutes do target
populations buy from local markets?
6
Methods of understanding access
• Information sources:
–
–
–
–
–
Expenditure data
Rapid Appraisal
Key Informants
Household survey
Focus group discussions
• by gender
• by target population
– Optimal ignorance, i.e., the fine art of asking questions
• Innovative delivery mechanisms may alleviate
identified constraints
7
Preferences
• Eliciting preferences can identify not only
preferred transfer but also issues and concerns
of households or individuals
• When eliciting preferences, need to provide
information on how transfers would most likely
be delivered
• Will delivery location and timing for different transfers
differ?
• Will cash transfers be inflation indexed?
• What shapes preferences?
8
Preferences
• Preferences across households may vary
– Income levels and sources, labor availability,
frequency of market access…
• Preferences within households may vary
– Gender, age, resource control, labor availability…
• Preferences drive elasticities
9
Eliciting preferences
• Preferences can be sensitive: who is asked and
where can shape findings
Source: Lentz (2009)
10
Income and Food Consumption
• Engel’s Law
– As income increases, the proportion of the budget
spent on food decreases
– Poor households spend proportionally more on food
than richer households
• Bennett’s Law
– As income increases, the proportion of the budget
spent on ‘starchy-staples’ decreases
• Reflects desire for dietary diversity
• Sharper than Engel’s Law
• Price increases of starchy staples are most
burdensome to poor households
11
Measures of Food Consumption
Relative to Household Income Level
(in Log form)
Source: Timmer et al. (1983). p. 57
12
Income and Consumption
• Normal goods
– Change in income changes demand for the normal
good in the same direction.
– Income effect and substitution effect work in the
same direction (combining effects)
– When the price of a normal good rises, households
may substitute other goods for it.
13
Income and Consumption
• Inferior goods
– Increase in income results in a decrease in demand
– Income effect is in the opposite direction from the
substitution effect (countervailing effects)
– For very poor households, demand for an inferior
good can increase when prices rise (and no
substitutes are available) or when income falls
• Households can no longer afford to buy more expensive
foods and thus spend more on cheaper, lower quality
calorie sources
14
Effects of a Food Price Increase
• All else equal, price increases for inferior goods
with few substitutes harm consumers’ welfare
more than equivalent price increases for
substitutable or normal goods
15
Income and Substitution Effects due to
a Price Increase
Source: Timmer et al. 1983. P. 44.
16
Elasticities
• General formula for elasticities:
eij = (Percentage change in variable i) / (Percentage change in
variable j)
• Own price elasticity
e0wn price = Quantity 1 % change / Price % change in quantity 1
• Income elasticity
ei = % change in demand for variable i / % change in income
• Cross price elasticity
17
Elasticity of demand (FEWs, Lesson 1,
p. 22)
18
What makes supply or demand elastic?
(FEWs, Lesson 1, p. 24)
19
What makes supply or demand elastic?
(FEWs, Lesson 1, p. 24)
20
Income and price elasticity for the bread and cereals food
group by per capita GDP
Source: Sited in World Food Programme, (2008) “PDPE Market Analysis Tool: Price and income elasticities” p.6: USDA-ESR
elasticities database, 1996, and GDP data from WDI 2006.
Note: Income and price elasticity estimates for the cereal and bread food groups are extracted from the USDA-ESR database collected
in 1996. GDP/capita values are in constant 2000 USD for the year 2004. These values were extracted from the WDI 2006 database.
21
The number of countries for which data was available is 107.
Income elasticities
• Income elasticity of demand
– Another definition of Engels Law: the income
elasticity of demand is less than one.
• Income elasticity of demand is closer to 1 for poorer
households than for richer households
• Income elasticity of demand
• ei = Percentage increase in demand
expenditure / Percentage increase in
income
• generally lies between 0 and 1
22
Example: Income Elasticity of Demand: Estimating
increased volume demanded for food due to cash
distribution
Source: Barrett et al. 2009
23
Price Elasticities
• A 1% increase in prices changes demand by x%
e0wn price = % change in demand for Good A / % change
in Price of Good A
• Price elasticities are generally below zero but for
poor households and staple products, price
elasticities may be above zero…why?
24
Price elasticities
• Use price elasticities to understand the affect of
increasing prices on consumers’ demand
• Also, use price elasticities to estimate the affect
of increased food supply on prices
• Example: food aid increases supply by 1%
– Price elasticity = -0.2 implies food price falls by 5%:
(1%/ x% = -0.2)
– Price elasticity = -0.6 implies food price falls by
1.7%: ( 1% / x%= -0.6)
25
Using Elasticities: Inverse Price Elasticity of Demand:
Estimating % Change in Price due to a % Change in
Supply: High Estimate
Price elasticity of demand: Less elastic (closer to zero)
-0.25
Inverse price elasticity of Demand: High estimate
-4.00
Estimate food aid delivery volume (i.e., addition to local supply)
25.00
Estimated market supply pre-delivery
% Supply Expansion due to Food Aid Deliveries
Estimated Percentage change in prices: High estimate
500.00
0.05
-20.00%
Source: Barrett et al. 2009
price elasticity = percent change in supply / percent change in price
x=change in price
-0.25=0.05%/x,
x = -20%
26
Using Elasticities: Inverse Price Elasticity of Demand:
Estimating % Change in Price due to a % Change in
Supply: Low Estimate
Price elasticity of demand: More elastic (further from zero)
-0.80
Inverse price elasticity of Demand: Low estimate
-1.25
Estimate food aid delivery volume (i.e., addition to local supply)
25.00
Estimated market supply pre-delivery
% Supply Expansion due to Food Aid Deliveries
Estimated Percentage change in prices: Low estimate
500.00
0.05
-6.25%
Source: Barrett et al. 2009
price elasticity = percent change in supply / percent change in price
-1.25=0.05%/x, x = -6.25%
27
Limitations of Elasticities
• Rare to find elasticities for the populations of
interest
– Try to find urban / rural and poor/non-poor
• Rare to find elasticities for the commodities of
interest
– Use sub-group
• Always compute high / low estimates and be
conservative
• Elasticities incorporate substitution effects
between foods, but not other second-round
coping mechanisms
28
Marginal Propensity to Consume
• As income increases by an amount, what is the
amount that demand increase?
MPC = Change in consumption / Change in income
• Consider estimating an MPC in the field
– Where income elasticities are unavailable or
unreliable
– Verify estimates
29
Computing MPCs in the field
• Ask likely recipient households how they would
spend a one-time gift.
• Using proportional piling, households indicate
what proportion of this gift would be spent on
food (or for key each commodity).
• The denominator is the size of the one-time gift
• The numerator is the value of the gift that would
be spent on a certain commodity.
MPC = Expenditure on good_1/ Value of transfer
30
Terms of Trade
• Terms of trade for good i and j is the ratio of
prices for goods i and j.
ToTij = (Price of good i)/(Price of good j)
• Compute for target groups:
ToTwr*= (day wages) / (price of 1 kg of rice)
*Sometime called the “net barter terms of trade”
31
Terms of Trade
1. Who are the target groups or livelihood groups
of interest?
2. What is/are the main cash income sources of
these groups, such as the sale of a cash crop,
livestock or daily labour?
3. What is/are the main staple foods consumed by
these groups?
4. Which data is required and/or available?
Source: WFP PDPE
32
Terms of Trade: Guinea Bissau
WFP 2008. “PDPE Market Analysis Tool: Terms of Trade” p. 6.
33
Terms of Trade: Limitations
•
•
•
•
•
Diverse livelihoods
Diverse consumables
Substitution effects
Dynamic
Local price data may differ from national data
34
Commodity Choice
• Choose commodities that are:
– Crucial for food security
•
•
•
•
staples
proteins
fats
other foods containing key micronutrients (e.g., iron)
– Consumed by the target population
• Assess whether seasonal consumption patterns differ
– Generally available on the market
• For example, corn-soy blend (CSB) is rarely available in large quantity
on local markets
– Nutritional assessments may suggest particular products
• Fresh fruit and vegetables in refugee camps
35
Commodity Choice
• Compute budget shares
– Most concerned about commodities whose price changes are
most likely to most impact the poor
» Focus on budget shares of the targeted populations
– A budget share is the ratio of the amount spent on one
commodity for a given time-period divided by the amount of
(cash and non-cash) budget earned for the same time period
36
Commodity Characteristics
• Assess particularly staples and substitutes, but also key
complementary goods and services, such as water,
medicine, fuel, or shelter.
• Is each candidate commodity an inferior or normal
good?
• What are the substitutes for these goods?
37
Commodity Choice
• The number of commodities to consider will depend
on:
–
–
–
–
–
Local consumption patterns
Nutritional concerns
Commodity characteristics (e.g., substitutability, dominance in diet)
Timeliness
Cost
• Keep in mind:
– Ask each trader about no more than 2-3 commodities (1-1.5 hours max)
– Commodity choice will inform the length of the supply chain (includes
source and destination markets)
38