The Goods Market
Download
Report
Transcript The Goods Market
The Goods Market
• Some definitions (or identities):
– Value of final production national income Y
– Total output sold total output purchased
• If aggregate sales is the same as aggregate
purchases, we can break down Y into the
various kinds of demand for output.
• i.e. we can focus on the composition of
aggregate demand for output Y.
BlCh3
1
Composition of aggregate demand Z
• Consumption
• Investment
C
I
– Fixed
• Residential (consumers)
• Non residential (firms)
– Inventories
• Government spending
• Net exports
– Exports
– Less Imports
BlCh3
G
NX
X
IM
2
• Consumption
– Goods and services purchased by consumers
– Some might be some sort of investment like durables
• Investment (not financial)
– Firms invest in new plants and equipments
– Consumers invest in new houses
• Government spending (on goods and services
only)
– Excludes transfers (e.g. medicare, S.S.)
– and interest payments on gov’t debt
– (total would be called government expenditures)
BlCh3
3
• Exports are foreign demand for domestic goods
and services (demand for Y) so they should be
included as demand for domestic output.
• Imports are domestic demand for foreign goods
(goods produced abroad) - they should not be
included in Y as they are not demand for
domestic output. However as they are already
included in consumption and other purchases they
must be subtracted.
• Net Exports = Exports - Imports
BlCh3
4
• Inventories corresponds to goods that
were produced during a certain year
I.e. during a specific accounting period
but were not sold during the same
accounting period.
– To get an accurate account of production
during the year, we must
• Subtract inventories at the beginning of the
year (they were produced in the previous
year)
• Add inventories at the end of the year
(produced this year but not sold)
BlCh3
5
Determination of aggregate demand Z
• By definition (identity):
Z C + I + G + X - IM in an open economy
ZC+I+G
in a closed economy
• Let’s assume
– Fixed prices (short run Keynesian model)
– One good (everything is in real term)
– Closed economy
BlCh3
6
Short run - medium run - long run
• Short run - period too short to allow prices
to adjust - fixed prices - unemployment
possible
• Medium run - economy is always at full
employment (labor market must adjust) prices adjust to bring economy back to full
employment - capital stock is fixed
• Long run - growth theory - capital stock
increases through investment in the
economy
BlCh3
7
Determinants of consumption C
• Let’s define YD - disposable income - as
YD Y - Tax + Transfer or Y - T (T is net tax)
• Consumption is determined by disposable
income: C increases as YD increases
• so consumption is a positive function of YD
C = C(YD) = C(Y-T)
this is a behavioral relation which can be
specified with the following linear form:
C = co + c 1 YD
c1 is the MPC
BlCh3
8
Consumption function
C
C = C(YD)
co
YD=Y-T
BlCh3
9
Endogenous versus exogenous variables
• Definition
– Endogenous variables are determined within the
model e.g. C , Y and YD
– Exogenous variables are determined outside of the
model, i.e. they are independent of any other variable
in the model
• Investment I is considered as an exogenous
variable in this chapter
• Government spending G and taxes T are also
exogenous variables - they are policy
instruments for the government.
BlCh3
10
Model
• C = c0 + c1 (Y-T)
• I = I (exogenous - given)
• G = G (exogenous - policy
variable)
• Z C + I + G by definition
• Y = Z (equilibrium condition)
BlCh3
11
Algebraic Solution
• Since in equilibrium, supply of goods (Y) should
be equal to aggregate demand (Z), by replacing
we get:
• Y = c0 + c1 (Y-T) + I + G
= c0 + c1Y -c1T + I + G
_
1
1
e
e
Y =
I
G
c
T)
Y
(c(c
I
G
c
T)
0
1
0
1
1c
1- c 1
1
1/(1-c1) is the multiplier m
and (c0 + I + G - c1T) is autonomous spending Z0
BlCh3
12
Graphical solution
Y=Z
Z
Z = Z0+c1Y
Z0
Ye
BlCh3
Y
13
The multiplier
• Assume a specific consumption function
C = 500 + .8(Y-T) i.e. MPC = .8
The multiplier m = 1/(1-c1) = 5
Since Ye = m (c0 + I + G - c1T)
If G increases by ∆G, Y will increase by
∆Y = m ∆G
In the example above an increase in G equal
to 100 will result in an increase in Y of 500
BlCh3
14
Effect of an increase in G
Z
Y=Z
Z = Z0+c1Y
4
2
∆G
Z’ = Z0+ ∆G +c1Y
3
1
Z0
Ye
BlCh3
Y’e
∆Y
Y
15
Explanation
• Starting at 1, the economy is in equilibrium.
• An increase in G equal to ∆G immediately translates into an
equal increase in aggregate demand : 1 to 2
• In 2 the economy is not in equilibrium as Z > Y so firms
must increase production by ∆G to meet the additional
demand: from 2 to 3
• In 3 the economy is still not in equilibrium (below ZZ’)
• As production increases by ∆G , income increases equally
so consumption demand will increase by c1 ∆G: this is an
additional increase in aggregate demand : 3 to 4
• Then production must increase again by c1 ∆G this time to
meet this new increase in aggregate demand and so on…
BlCh3
16
Rational
• Production (income) depends on demand
as Y = Z
in equilibrium
• Demand depends on income
as Z = C + I + G
and C = C(Y)
BlCh3
17
• When there is an exogenous increase in demand,
production will increase equally, and this increase in
production (i.e. in income) results in an additional
increase in demand.
• However the additional increase in demand is smaller
than the original increase because the marginal
propensity to consume is less than 1 (some of the
increase in income is saved): this process will not result
in an infinite increase in output as the additional
increases in demand get smaller and smaller and tend
towards zero.
BlCh3
18
Alternative calculation of the multiplier
Per
iod
1
2
3
4
∆G ∆G
Total increase
(many periods)
∆G
c1 ∆G c12 ∆G
∆Y
∆G
∆C
c1 ∆G c12 ∆G c13 ∆G
(1+c1+c12+ …) ∆G
1
=
G
1- c1
(c1+c12+c13+ …) ∆G
3 ∆G (1+c +c 2+c 3+ …) ∆G
∆Z ∆G c1 ∆G c12 ∆G c1
1 1
1
BlCh3
19
Alternative approach: Investment = saving
• Approach used by Keynes in the “General Theory
of Employment, Interest and Money” 1936
• By definition, private saving is what is not
consumed out of disposable income:
Sp YD - C
hence Sp Y - T - C
or Y C + Sp + T
• The equilibrium condition of the model above was:
Y=C+I+G
By replacing, it becomes I = Sp + T - G
BlCh3
20
Interpretation
• In a one person economy, investment equals
savings because the decision to save and to
invest is made by the same person.
e.g. Robinson Crusoe’s island
BlCh3
21
Role of government:
• In the above equation, the government
1. takes a share of income in the form of tax
2. spends it in the economy in the form of G
so T - G corresponds to the amount of tax receipts
that the government did not spend, i.e. that the
government saved.
• In sum, T - G (the budget surplus) can be
interpreted as the government saving Sg.
BlCh3
22
Solution of the model using the
alternative equilibrium condition
• Let’s derive the saving function from the
consumption function (c1 is the MPC)
• C = c0 + c1YD and Sp YD - C
• SP = YD - c0 - c1YD = - c0 + (1 - c1)YD
• Sp = - c0 + (1 - c1)(Y - T) with MPS = (1 - c1)
– Note that MPC + MPS = 1 as mentioned earlier
• We can now use the saving function and the new
equilibrium condition to find equilibrium Y (Ye)
BlCh3
23
• I = Sp + (T - G) (equilibrium condition)
= - c0 + (1 - c1)(Y - T) + T - G
= - c0 + (1 - c1)Y - (1 - c1)T + T - G
= - c0 + (1 - c1)Y - T + c1T + T - G
(1 - c1)Y = c0 + I + G - c1T
Finally
_
1
e
Y
(c 0 I G - c1T)
1- c1
as before.
BlCh3
24
Problem # 2 P. 62
C = 160 + 0.6 YD
I = 150
G = 150
T = 100
a. In equilibrium Y = 160 + 0.6 (Y-T) + 150 + 150
i.e. Y - 0.6Y = 160 - (0.6*T) + 150 + 150
Y = [1/(1-0.6)] (160 - 60 + 150 + 150)
Y = 2.5 * 400 = 1000
BlCh3
25
b. YD = Y - T = 1000 - 100 = 900
c. C = 160 + 0.6*900 = 700
Problem # 3
a. Z = C + I + G = 700 + 150 + 150 = 1000
so Y = Z = 1000 (equilibrium condition)
b. If G = 110 ∆G = - 40
as the multiplier m = 2.5 and ∆Y = m ∆G
∆Y = - 100 and the new equilibrium Y is 900
consumption drops by c1* ∆Y or - 60 to 640
And Z = C’ + I + G’ = 640 + 150 + 110 = 900
BlCh3
26
c. Private savings Sp = Y - T - C
= 900 - 100 - 640 = 160
Government savings Sg = T - G
= 100 - 110 = -10
Equilibrium condition: I = Sp + Sg
150 = 160 - 10 = 150
BlCh3
27