L13-14-Vietnam - Agricultural & Applied Economics
Download
Report
Transcript L13-14-Vietnam - Agricultural & Applied Economics
Globalization, Growth, and Trade
Lectures 13-14:
Specific Factors Model (SFM)
0
Overview - Today
Motivation: Bringing ‘structure’ of economy into trade
discussion, a quick look at global export shares and
comparative advantage
Overview of the Specific Factors Model (SFM)
Analytical pieces of the SFM
Production function
Production possibility frontier
Production function and implied factor returns
4 quadrant model (labor, 2 production functions, possibility
frontier)
Trade, production and factor payments in the SFM
Analysis: winners and losers from global market shocks
1
Regional export shares by sector
2
Primary product export shares
Latin Am: 50% avg., but 85% for Andean countries
60% of Mercosur inc. Bolivia and Chile;
Over 65%: Argentina, Belize, Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Nicaragua,
Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay, Venezuela
Under 40% - Costa Rica and Mexico
Comparative advantage of most of LA is clear
S.S. Africa: most countries are mainly primary exporters
4 countries with <70% (Togo, Senegal, South Africa, Mauritius)
6 with 70-80% share (Guinea, Kenya, Madagascar, Niger, Zambia,
Zimbabwe)
The other 25 have > 80% primary export share
3
Comparative Advantage Comparisons
If export shares => comp advantage, then most of L Am
& Africa have comparative advantage in primary
products.
What implications might this have for development?
Why does it matter to poverty?
Recall that Yh = wLh + rKh: how would expanding primary
products shape household incomes? What does your answer
depend on?
Why might you be concerned about the poverty implications of
comparative advantage in primary products versus
manufacturing?
We can get more on this once we dig further into our next trade
model
4
Political economy implications
HO-SS predicts aggregate gains from trade, but also
losses for some groups
--> Functional (self-interest) basis for some positions
on trade:
Owners of abundant factors in favor
Owners of scarce factors opposed
Examples?
5
Overview of Specific Factors Model (SFM)
2 good model (like H-O)
But capital (or natural resource) is specific to sectors
(cannot be moved to other sector)
Does this make sense?
Can a coffee farm become a clothing factory in short term?
In long term?
In SFM, only labor is mobile between sectors
Use SFM to study how changes in trade patterns, FDI, and
technology affect economic structure and incomes when
factor-specificity limits adjustment
Helps us to see winners and losers from trade in a slightly
different way.
Production function – 1 sector
Factors of production
Production function
Diminishing returns
VMP and factor payments
7
Production Function
Rice (tons)
ƒx(L, K)
28
27
25
20
0
10
20
30
40
Labor days
• Constant returns to scale in (L,K), so dim. returns to
L when quantity of K is fixed
8
Production Function (more K -> more rice)
ƒx(L, K+)
Rice (tons)
ƒx(L, K)
28
27
25
20
0
10
20
30
40
Labor days
• Constant returns to scale in (L,K), so dim. returns to
L when quantity of K is fixed (irrigated paddy)
9
Calculating Factor Returns
X
slope = w/px
X = (w/px)Lx + πx
ƒx(K,L)
X0
Revenue = costs
πx
X*px = w*Lx + rx*Kx
or: X = (w/px)Lx + πx
where: πx = (rx/px)*Kx
0
Lx 0
Lx
• Assume: wage = value of labor’s marginal product
• Return on labor (= wage) = slope of tangent to function
• Return on stock of sector-specific capital is height 0πx = (rx/px)Kx
10
(Derivation of factor returns)
Total revenue of the firm:
pxX = wL + rxKx
By assumption, the value of output is fully divided
between workers and capital owners
Dividing both sides by px:
X = (w/px)L + (r/px)Kx
= (w/px)L + πx
Note: w/px is known as the product wage in sector X
Distribution between L and K: X – (w/px)L = πx
Higher wage (steeper slope on w/px) implies lower profit
share. Flatter slope implies higher profit share
11
The specific factors model
Assume 2 goods, X and M
Each sector uses specific capital, Kx, Km
--> prod’n fns yj = ƒj(L, Kj), j = X, M
Labor is ‘mobile’ (can be reallocated) between X
and M production
Total labor force is fixed and fully employed:
L = Lx + Lm
In equilibrium, same wage offered in both sectors
For given Kx and Km, when labor is fully employed, can
only increase output (create jobs) in one industry by
reducing output (destroying jobs) in the other
12
General Equilibrium – Supply Side
Production function M
M
Prod’n Poss. Frontier,
Maps total production possible
given PFs and labor
ƒm(Lm,Km)
L
0
50
X
Production function x
ƒx(Lx,Kx)
Labor constraint
45o
50
L
13
Autarky (no trade)
M
•
uA
MA
•L
0
m
L
pA
•XA
X
Lx •
LA
45o
L
14
From Autarky to Trade
p* > pA
•
M
uT
•
MA
uA
pA
•
MT
p*
•L
•
m
L
0
•XA • XT
MT < M A
LMT < LMA
…
uT = uA
LT = LA
X
Lx •
LA
•
LT
L
15
Trade, income, distribution in SFM
Integration with world economy raises aggregate real
income & cons. welfare
Structure of production and labor allocation change in
predictable ways
What happens to returns to specific factors? (hint:
Stolper-Samuelson - see notes from Week 1)
What happens to the real wage?
16
Aggregate Income
M
uT
uA
pA
pT
0
L
YA YT X
LA
Compare old and new
incomes at constant prices!
LT
45o
L
17
(Aggregate income change)
YT = aggregate income from production of the combination
(XT, MT) valued at world prices pT, measured in terms of
good X (the value of X that could be bought with that
much income)
Compare: YA = aggregate income from production of the
combination (XA, MA), valued at world prices pT, measured
in terms of good X
YT > YA says the economy is better off in aggregate
18
Changes in factor payments
(w/pM)T
slope =
M
pA
MA
(w/pM)A
T
M
L
LA
LT
0
XA
TX
pT
X
45o
L
19
(Changes in factor payments)
Moving from autarky to trade raises X output and
employment, lowers M output and employment
Demand for KX rises; πXT > πXA
Demand for KM falls; πMT > πMA
Demand for L in M falls; with KM fixed , law of
diminishing returns says that productivity of
remaining workers rises, so (w/pM)A < (w/pM)T
Demand for L in X rises; with KX fixed,
(w/pX)A > (w/pX)T
Are workers better off or worse off?
20
Comparative Advantage in Agriculture
Capitalists
(Km)
Landowners
(Kx)
Workers
(L)
Effect of rise in
px on nominal
inc.
Effect of rise in
px on real inc.
(a) When
consume
mostly X
(b) When
consume
mostly M
21
Comparative Advantage in Agriculture
Capitalists
(Km)
Landowners
(Kx)
Workers
(L)
lose
gain
gain
(a) When
consume
mostly X
lose
gain
lose?
(b) When
consume
mostly M
lose
gain
gain?
Effect of rise in
px on nominal
inc.
Effect of rise in
px on real inc.
22
Comparative Advantage in Manufacturing
Capitalists
(Kx)
Landowners
(Km)
Workers
(L)
Effect of rise in
px on nom.
income
Effect of rise in
px on real inc.
(a) When
consume
mostly X
(b) When
consume
mostly M
23
Comparative Advantage in Manufacturing
Capitalists
(Kx)
Landowners
(Km)
Workers
(L)
gain
lose
gain
(a) When
consume
mostly X
gain
lose
lose?
(b) When
consume
mostly M
gain
lose
gain?
Effect of rise in
px on nom.
income
Effect of rise in
px on real inc.
24
Distributional & poverty effects
Real specific factor returns follow own prices: for a
rise in px/pm, πx will rise, πm will fall
Real wage change is indeterminate:
Wage rises rel. to pm, but falls rel. to px
H’hold welfare: aggregate has risen, but
Gains for owners of capital in X
Losses for owners of capital in M
Workers’ welfare change is ambiguous
25
Discussion
If we have data on asset ownership & cons. patterns, can
compute changes in Rh and poverty for groups
Poverty effects depend on distribution of assets as well as
on changes in payments such as wages and rents
Notice that we have assumed labor is mobile between
sectors. Realistic? What if it is not?
SFM vs H-O: which is more realistic? When?
What about more complex models, for example with
some endogenous product prices (nontradables?)
See next class…
26