Eco120Int_Lecture11

Download Report

Transcript Eco120Int_Lecture11

ECO 120
Macroeconomics
Week 11
Economic Growth
Lecturer
Dr. Rod Duncan
Topics
• Long run in the AD-AS model
• Growth or macroeconomics of the long-run
Long-run in the AD-AS model
• So far, all the macroeconomics we have
done is short-run.
• In terms of a story, we have:
– A beginning where the economy starts off in
long-run equilibrium at the natural rate of
output and some price level; and
– A middle where some shock occurs and the
economy is affected, so Y shifts up or down
and P shifts up or down.
Beginning and middle
AS1
P
Y*
AS0
P1
P0
AD
Y1
Y0
Y
• A rise in oil prices
raises the cost of
production for all
producers and shifts
the SR AS curve up/to
the left.
• At the old prices, AD
> AS, so prices rise
and output falls.
A story with no end?
• And then what?
• And then nothing, so far. Our story does not
have an end yet.
• A good story, such as DreamWork’s “Shrek”has:
– Beginning- Shrek in his swamp;
– Middle- Shrek goes on a journey and rescues a
princess;
– End- Shrek returns to his swamp- a better ogre and
with his princess.
A story with no end?
A Story
• So all good stories
have a circular
pattern. At the end,
we comes back to the
beginning.
• Even in an economics
story, we have to
have this sort of
pattern.
End
Beginning
Middle
An end = Natural rate
• For the “natural rate of output” to make any
sense, in the long-run the economy must return
to this natural rate.
• Some design of the economy must push the
economy back to the natural rate- all booms and
all recessions eventually end.
• So what process pushes us back to the long-run
equilibrium- wage demands!
• All booms and all recessions come to an end
because companies and workers change
wages.
So where are we?
• The oil price shock
caused the As curve
to shift. We have
inflation, and a
recession- cost-pull
inflation.
• Unemployment is
high and output is
low.
• Firms are not hiring.
AS1
P
Middle Y*
AS0
P1
P0
Beginning
AD
Y1
Y0
Y
Adjustment after a recession
• Unemployment is high, but the firms are
not hiring workers because the firms’
energy and transportation bills are high.
• We have a surplus of labour at the current
price of labour- what effect do surpluses
have in markets?
– The price of labour gets bid down. Workers
offer lower wages simply to get jobs.
– The same as a surplus of oranges will lead to
a fall in price of oranges.
Adjustment after a recession
• As wages drop, the cost of production to firms
drops. So we would expect that the AS curve
will shift down/out to the right.
• [Remember: A shift down in the supply curve
means that firms are willing to supply more at
the same price or supply the same amount at a
lower price.]
• As the AS curve shifts down, output rises, prices
fall and unemployment drops, until we are back
at the natural rate of output again.
Adjustment after a recession
• A high level of
unemployment means
that workers are willing to
accept lower wages.
• A fall in W pushes the AS
down/right, so that Y rises
and unemployment falls.
• Fall in W continues until
We get back to Y*.
AS1
P
Middle Y*
AS2
P1
P2
AD
Y1
Y0
Y
Alternative solution- fiscal
• So the adjustment process for an oil price boom
and recession is for wages to fall.
• But this requires a period of high unemployment
and falling wages. Is there another alternative?
• What if the government responded to the
recession by stimulating AD through fiscal
policy?
• An increase in G would shift the AD curve to the
right, which would raise Y at the cost of higher P.
Alternative solution- fiscal
• During the recession,
we have low output
(Y1) and high
unemployment.
• Fiscal policy
stimulates AD0 to AD1.
• Output rises, and
unemployment falls.
But inflation rises, as
P rises to P2.
P
Middle Y*
AS1
P2
P1
P0
AD0
Y1
Y0
AD2
Y
Adjustment after a boom
• Our first adjustment
scenario was a
recession. Imagine
instead that we start
with a boom- an
increase in I due to
improved business
expectations.
• Investment rises, and
so the AD curve shifts
to the right.
P
Y*
AS0
P1
Middle
P0
Beginning
AD0
Y0
Y1
AD1
Y
Adjustment after a boom
• Y increases to Y1, so we have a boom with high
output and low unemployment.
• We have inflation, as P rises to P1.
• A low level of unemployment and a high level of
output means that there is excess demand for
labour (you will hear “skills shortage”).
• Excess demand for any good will lead to a rise
in prices, so the wage rate is pushed up as firms
offer workers more to stay or be hired.
Adjustment after a boom
• An increase in wages
will push the AS curve
up/in, as firms’
production costs rise.
• As the AS curve shifts
up, output falls, prices
rise and we move
back to Y*.
P
AS1
Y*
AS0
P2
P1
Middle
AD0
Y0
Y1
AD1
Y
Adjustment after a boom
• So the adjustment process after a boom is
for wages to rise, which will push the AS
curve up.
• So a boom will lead to a wage rise, which
will push inflation even higher.
• Is there a way to adjust to a boom that
does not require further inflation?
Alternative solution – monetary
• If the RBA responds to
the future increase in
wages by raising interest
rates now, we can avoid
the wage inflation
following a boom.
• A rise in i leads to a drop
in I, which shifts the AD
curve left.
• Output and prices fall
today.
P
Y*
AS0
P1
Middle
P2
AD2
Y0
Y1
AD1
Y
Long-run equilibrium
• Adjustment to a bust
– AS shifts up to AS1.
– Output falls, and prices rise
in the short-run.
– Wage demands shift AS
down to AS2.
– Output rises and prices fall
as we adjust to long-run.
– In long-run, output back to
natural rate, and prices
return to initial levels.
AS1
P
Y*
AS0=AS2
P1
P0
AD
Y1
Y0
Y
Long-run equilibrium
• Adjustment to a boom
– AD shifts out to AD1.
– Output and prices rise
in the short-run.
– Wage demands shift
AS left to AS2.
– Output falls and prices
rise as we adjust to
long-run.
– In long-run, output
back to natural rate,
and prices higher.
P
Y*
End
AS2
AS0
P2
P1
Middle
P0
Beginning
AD0
Y0
Y1
AD1
Y
Long-run growth
• We are ultimately interested in the level of
resources each individual in society has access
to. The level of resources will then somewhat
determine what opportunities each person has.
• So we are ultimately interested in GDP per
person of an economy. Growth is the increase
of GDP per capita over time.
• Y / N = output per person
Long-run growth
• But not every person in an economy is “economically
productive”, so if we want to link “worker productivity”
and GDP per capita , we need:
• Y / N = (Y/Nw) (Nw/N)
• Y/Nw = output per worker depends on labour productivity,
which depends on skills in workforce, capital, tech
• Nw/N = labour force participation rate which depends on
cultural attitudes and aging of the population
Labour force participation
• Growth in GDP per capita can come from
increasing Nw/N.
– As people move from subsistence farming on
rural areas to paid employment in urban
areas, labour force participation rises.
– As women move out of unpaid domestic work
to paid domestic work, labour force
participation rises.
• But obviously there is a limit to this sort of
growth.
Labour force participation
Australian Labour Force Part'n
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
19
50
19
53
19
56
19
59
19
62
19
65
19
68
19
71
19
74
19
77
19
80
19
83
19
86
19
89
19
92
19
95
19
98
0
Labour force participation
• And as the Australian population ages, we
will eventually see this LFP start to
decline, as the population of retirees
increases.
• This will be a major challenge for Australia
in the relatively near future.
Output per worker
• Output per worker, Y/Nw, is the main source of
growth in Australia.
• So growth in Australia depends on increasing
the productivity of our workers. What
determines how productive a worker is?
– The skills of the worker.
– The physical capital the worker uses.
– The level of technology the worker and capital have
access to.
Output per worker
Australian Real GDP per Worker
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
19
50
19
53
19
56
19
59
19
62
19
65
19
68
19
71
19
74
19
77
19
80
19
83
19
86
19
89
19
92
19
95
19
98
0
Output per worker
• Output per worker was $22,000 in 1950
and $52,000 in 2000 in constant dollars.
(Once we remove the effects of inflation.)
• So how are Australian workers today over
twice as productive as workers in 1950?
– New technologies (mechanization, robotics,
computers, etc)
– More capital (powered floor polishers instead
of mops)
Output per capita
• So once we combine labour force changes
and worker productivity changes, we wind
up with change in output per capita over
time.
• Real GDP per capita was $9,200 in 1950
and $25,500 in 2000.
• Australians in 2000 have almost twice as
much resources per person than
Australians did in 1950.
Long-run growth in Australia
Australian Real GDP per Capita
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
19
50
19
53
19
56
19
59
19
62
19
65
19
68
19
71
19
74
19
77
19
80
19
83
19
86
19
89
19
92
19
95
19
98
0
Long-run growth in Australia
• While there was a temporary blip in GDP
in early 1950s, 1980s and 1990s, the
overall picture is one of steadily increasing
GDP per person over time.
• What can be done to ensure growth in
Australia?
– Increasing productivity per worker.
• Increasing skill levels, increasing capital
and increasing technology.
But remember…
• Remember what it is that GDP measures:
the market value of all goods and services
sold in the economy.
– Ignores non-market goods, such as domestic
work and pollution.
– Does not include black market goods.
– Having longer holidays might make for a
happier workforce, but would lower GDP.
Growth and economic development
What about other countries?
• Relative to the rest of the developed world,
Australia is a fast-growing economy.
• Australia is behind the United States, but
ahead of countries such as the UK and
NZ.
• Relative to our neighbours (East Asia),
Australia is a very prosperous country.
Relative to developed countries
Relative Real GDP per Capita
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
Australia
USA
UK
NZ
10000
5000
19
50
19
53
19
56
19
59
19
62
19
65
19
68
19
71
19
74
19
77
19
80
19
83
19
86
19
89
19
92
19
95
19
98
0
Relative to our neighbours
Relative Real GDP per Capita
30000
25000
20000
Australia
15000
10000
5000
19
50
19
53
19
56
19
59
19
62
19
65
19
68
19
71
19
74
19
77
19
80
19
83
19
86
19
89
19
92
19
95
19
98
0
Japan
Hong Kong
Indonesia
Convergence
• “Convergence” is the idea that we would
expect countries that are initially poorer
should grow faster than countries that are
richer.
• Why?
– Technology- Poor countries can piggy-back
for free off the technology developed by rich
countries.
– Capital flow- We expect investors to rush to
invest in countries with cheap wages.
Convergence
• Over time, we expect poor countries to
grow faster than rich countries, so GDP
per capita across different countries
should “converge” over time.
• Is this idea true?
• We saw that certain countries like Japan
and South Korea started off poorer than
Australia but caught up.
Catching up?
East Asian Miracle?
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
Australia
Japan
USA
S Korea
China
10000
5000
19
50
19
53
19
56
19
59
19
62
19
65
19
68
19
71
19
74
19
77
19
80
19
83
19
86
19
89
19
92
19
95
19
98
0
Malaysia
But look!
African development?
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
Australia
USA
Kenya
Nigeria
Uganda
10000
5000
19
50
19
53
19
56
19
59
19
62
19
65
19
68
19
71
19
74
19
77
19
80
19
83
19
86
19
89
19
92
19
95
19
98
0
Malawi
Log graph
Log scale graph of African problems
100000
10000
Australia
USA
1000
Kenya
Nigeria
100
Uganda
Malawi
10
20
00
19
90
19
80
19
70
19
60
19
50
1
Consequences of growth
Life
Adult
Enrollm
ent
Expectancy
Literacy
in Edu
per capita
HDI
Rank
Norway
78.5
100
97
29,918
0.942
1
Australia
78.9
100
116
25,693
0.939
5
USA
77
100
95
34,142
0.939
6
Japan
81
100
82
26,755
0.933
9
Indonesia
66.2
86.9
65
3,043
0.684
110
Kenya
50.8
82.4
51
1,022
0.513
134
Uganda
44
67.1
45
1,208
0.444
150
Malawi
40
60.1
73
615
0.4
163
GDP