Evolution of the price of bread
Download
Report
Transcript Evolution of the price of bread
Pure
Exchange
Chapter 6
Slides by Pamela L. Hall
Western Washington University
©2005, Southwestern
Introduction
Economists have different treatments for
addressing economic problems
If problem of allocation is generally localized in one
market
Partial-equilibrium analysis would provide correct solution
• Only one segment of an economy is analyzed
Without consideration for possible interactions with other segments
If it is a general problem infecting numerous
markets or whole economy
Use general equilibrium analysis
• Study of interaction among agents across markets within an
economy
2
Introduction
A (general) equilibrium model of all markets, where supply
and demand for each commodity are equated
Will result in necessary conditions for economic efficiency
Achieved by agents trading commodities to increase their
utility
Agents will trade until all gains are exhausted
Efficiency gains from agents’ trading are most apparent
when households are the only agents
Initially endowed with some quantities of commodities, and there is
no production
• Called a pure-exchange economy
Supply of each commodity is sum of each household’s endowment of that
commodity
3
Introduction
This chapter
Explores gains from trade in a pure exchange economy
• Edgeworth box is a method of illustrating these gains for two
traders
Investigates efficiency of a free-market price system for
allocating commodities
• Relate this to Pareto-efficient allocation using First and Second
Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics
Develops trial-and-error process of establishing an
equilibrium set of prices
• Relates this to optimal social-welfare allocation
Discusses a fair allocation of initial resources
• Yielding an optimal social-welfare allocation
4
Gains from Trade
In pure-exchange economies, we assume a certain amount of various
commodities exist
Problem is to efficiently allocate these commodities among households
An allocation of existing commodities is efficient if no one household can be
made better off without making some other household worse off
Necessary condition for such an efficient allocation of commodities is
• MRS1 = MRS2 = … = MRSn
Subscripts denote households
n represents number of households
MRS measures how much a household is willing to trade one commodity for another
When how much each household is willing to trade one commodity for
another are equal
Gains from trade are exhausted
• Any reallocation of commodities will not increase utility of one household without
decreasing utility of another
5
Two-Commodity and TwoHousehold Economy
Consider an economy with two commodities,
bread and fish, and two individuals
(households), Robinson (R) and Friday (F )
50 units of bread and 100 units of fish are to
be allocated
Can be allocated in various ways
• Could be all allocated to Robinson, all to Friday, or
•
some combination in between
Egalitarian allocation would divide commodities
equally between Robinson and Friday
Such an allocation may not be efficient if Robinson’s and
Friday’s MRSs are not equal at this equal allocation
6
Two-Commodity and TwoHousehold Economy
Suppose Robinson’s MRSR (bread for fish) = 2/1 at an equal allocation
where Robinson obtains 25 units of bread and 50 units of fish
Friday’s MRSF (bread for fish) = 1/1
Allocation does not result in an efficient allocation because
MRSR = 2 ≠ 1 = MRSF
If 2 units of bread are taken from Robinson with 1 unit traded to Friday
for 1 fish
Level of utility remains the same with 1 unit of bread leftover
• Indicated in Table 6.1
By trading, utilities of Robinson and Friday remain unchanged, with 1
unit of bread left over
Represents gains from trade
• Could then be divided between Robinson and Friday
Resulting in their utility increasing
7
Table 6.1 Gains from trade
8
Two-Commodity and TwoHousehold Economy
As long as MRSs between Robinson and
Friday are unequal
Gains from trade are possible
Many possible trades that will result in gains
Use Robinson’s and Friday’s initial
endowments and indifference curves to
determine all possible trades leading to gains
Shown in Figure 6.1
9
Figure 6.1 Preferences and endowments
for the two-commodity…
10
Edgeworth Box
Provides a convenient method for representing the two
households’ preferences and endowments in one diagram
See Figure 6.2
Construct box by turning preference space for Friday 180
Place it on top of Robinson’s preference space at point where their
endowments are together
• Point C in Figure 6.2
Horizontal width represents total quantity of fish available
Vertical height represents total quantity of bread available
Size of box depends on total amount of fish and bread available in
economy
Every point inside box represents a feasible allocation of fish and
bread
11
Figure 6.2 Edgeworth box in a
pure-exchange economy
12
Edgeworth Box
An allocation is feasible if total quantity consumed of each commodity is equal to
total available from endowments
xR1 + xF1 = eR1 +eF1, commodity 1, fish
xR2 + xF2 = eR2 +eF2, commodity 2, bread
An allocation where Robinson receives nothing and Friday receives all is a
feasible allocation
Represented by 0R in Figure 6.2
• Robinson’s utility is minimized and Friday’s utility is maximized
At 0F, allocation is nothing for Friday and everything for Robinson
Friday’s utility is minimized and Robinson’s maximized
Feasible allocations between these two extreme points represent combinations
of commodities with varying levels of satisfaction for both Robinson and Friday
For a movement toward 0R, Friday receives more of either fish or bread
• Increases her utility
Robinson receives less, which decreases his utility
• Reverse occurs for a movement toward 0F
13
Pareto-Efficient Allocation
Allocation where there is no way to make all
households better off
No way to make some households better off
without making someone else worse off
All gains from trade are exhausted
• Illustrated in Figure 6.3
• Point C is not Pareto efficient
Possible to reallocate commodities in such a manner that one
household can be made better off without making another worse off
• Any point within shaded lens represents a gain (Pareto
improvement)
• At points A, B, and all points on the cord
MRSR = MRSF and are Pareto-efficient allocations
14
Figure 6.3 Efficiency in a pureexchange economy
15
Pareto-Efficient Allocation
Cord from points A to B is called the core solution
All gains from trade are exhausted
Exact solution point within this core depends on
bargaining strength of two agents
If Friday is a relatively strong bargainer
• She will receive more of gains from trade
Solution will be closer to point B
Alternatively, if Robinson has the upper hand
• He will receive a larger portion of gains
Solution will approach point A
16
Contract Curve (Pareto-Efficient
Allocation)
Optimal allocation resulting from allocating
commodities between Robinson and Friday
Will depend on how initial total endowment of
bread and fish is divided between them
• If Robinson initially has most of the bread and fish
Optimal allocation near point D in Figure 6.4 may result
The more fish and bread a household initially
has, the higher the level of utility it can achieve
• Distribution of income determines resulting Paretoefficient allocation
17
Contract Curve (Pareto-Efficient
Allocation)
By varying allocation of initial endowments
Can trace out complete set of Pareto-efficient allocations
• Called a contract curve
Illustrated in Figure 6.4
• Contract curve represents a curve in interior of Edgeworth box
Intersecting tangencies between indifference curves for two agents
MRSs are equal
• If efficient allocations exist, where an agent will not consume a
positive amount of all commodities
Contract curve will correspond with a segment of an axis (corner
solution)
MRSs will not equate
18
Figure 6.4 Contract curve in a
pure-exchange economy
19
Contract Curve (Pareto-Efficient
Allocation)
Any point not on contract curve is inefficient
Agents will adjust terms of trade until a contract is made
Represents all Pareto-efficient allocations for a given set of
initial endowments
Every point on contract curve results in economic efficiency
• Social welfare is not maximized at every point
Movement along a contract curve will increase one agent’s
utility at expense of reduced utility for other agent
Maximum social welfare depends on
Economic efficiency
Optimal distribution of income
20
Contract Curve (Pareto-Efficient
Allocation)
Pareto optimality does provide a necessary condition for an
allocation to maximize social welfare
No inefficiencies in resource allocation exist
• Necessary condition for maximum social welfare
Major inadequacy of Pareto-welfare criterion
Does not lead to a complete social ranking of alternative allocations
for an economy
• Useless criterion for many policy propositions
Some analytical results can be obtained with a Paretowelfare criterion
For example, point rationing is ordinarily better than fixed-ration
quantities
21
Efficiency of a Price System
A medium of exchange is particularly useful as
number of households increases
Process of bartering becomes cumbersome
All commodities are valued by this medium
Medium is accepted in exchange for commodities
Medium of exchange is money
Money is accepted not for direct utility it provides
But for indirect utility via commodities it can purchase
22
Efficiency of a Price System
Allocation device that has received by far the greatest
attention by economists is price system
Assumes all commodities are valued in market by their money
equivalence
Permits decentralization of allocation decisions
Provides a method for relating household preferences with supply at
a reduced cost for society
• Prices act as signals to economic agents in guiding their supply and
demand decisions
Under a perfectly competitive price system, households have no
control over market prices
• Take prices as given
Yields a Pareto-efficient market system
23
Efficiency of a Price System
In a perfectly competitive price system
Correspondence between Pareto-efficient allocation of resources
and perfectly competitive price system is exact
• Called First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics
Provides formal and general confirmation of Adam Smith’s invisible hand
Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics states
Every Pareto-efficient allocation has an associated perfectly
competitive set of prices
States possibility of achieving any desired Pareto-efficient allocation
as a market-based equilibrium using an appropriate distribution of
income
• Not every Pareto-efficient allocation is a social-welfare optimum
24
Efficiency of a Price System
Recall that Pareto efficiency in exchange requires
MRS1 = MRS2 = … = MRSn
• For n households in economy
For utility maximization subject to a wealth or income constraint,
each household equates its MRS with price ratio
• MRS(x2 for x1) = p1/p2
Every household faces same price ratio
Market in equilibrium creates a societal trade-off rate that is a correct
reflection of every household’s trade-off rate
• Information on this trade-off rate (if it could be gathered) would require
large expenditures by a government
Instead, this trade-off can be generated by perfectly competitive interaction
of supply and demand
At zero governmental cost
25
Offer Curve
Traces out points where household maximizes utility for a
given level of income across various ratios of prices
See Figure 6.5
At each point household’s indifference curve is tangent to a
budget constraint for a given price ratio
Represents how much a household is willing to offer one
commodity in exchange for the other at a given price ratio
Analogous to price consumption curve with focal point at
initial endowment e
At alternative price ratios, endowment is affordable
Every point on offer curve is at least as good as agent’s endowment
point e
26
Figure 6.5 Offer curve
27
Offer Curve
Represents a set of demanded bundles
Each demanded bundle associated with a price
ratio
• As price ratio continues to increase, new demanded
bundles unfold
• Locus of all these demanded bundles is offer curve
• Each household has an offer curve and initial
endowment of commodities
• Relating offer curves and endowment of two
households in an Edgeworth box
Walrasian equilibrium is illustrated in Figure 6.6
28
Figure 6.6 Pareto efficiency and
competitive pricing
29
Offer Curve
Where two offer curves intersect, point A,
price ratio is same for both Robinson and
Friday
Demanded bundles exactly match supply
MRSs for Robinson and Friday are equated
• Yields one-to-one correspondence between Pareto
efficiency and perfectly competitive markets
MRSs are both equal to p1*/p2*
•
Aggregate supply equals aggregate demand for
each of the commodities
• Households are maximizing their utility
30
Walras’s Law
Static equilibrium conditions are generally
theoretical results in economics
Economy does not operate on a set of natural laws
that describe its evolution
Process of how an economy in disequilibrium
reaches an equilibrium state (called tâtonnement
stability) can be described only in limited detail
First described by Walras
Tâtonnement is French
• Means groping or trial and error
31
Walras’s Law
For example, if at p1'/p2' quantity demanded for fish
is greater than quantity supplied and quantity
demanded for bread is less than quantity supplied
Price ratio would rise
• Quantity demanded for fish would decline and that for bread
would increase
Adjustment would continue until prices converge to competitive
equilibrium levels
Adjustment assumes prices will respond to market
shortages and surpluses
If prices are rigid then tâtonnement process will not work
32
Walras’s Law
Friday’s demand functions for commodities x1 and
x2, respectively
x1F(p1, p2, e1F, e2F) and x2F( p1, p2, e1F, e2F)
Robinson’s demand functions
x1R(p1,p2,e1R,e2R) and x2R( p1, p2,e1R,e2R)
Walrasian equilibrium set of prices (p1*, p2*) is
where aggregate demand equals aggregate supply
33
Walras’s Law
Alternatively, this Walrasian equilibrium may be represented
in terms of aggregate excess demand functions
For zj > 0 commodity j is in excess demand
For zj < 0 commodity j is in excess supply
• For j = 1, 2
34
Walras’s Law
Walrasian equilibrium exists when these
aggregate excess demand functions are zero
Result of specifying markets for commodities in
terms of excess demand is Walras’s Law
• Value of aggregate excess demand is zero for not only the
equilibrium set of prices (p1*, p2*) but for all possible prices
In two-commodity economy, if z1 > 0 (excess
demand), then, given positive prices, z2 < 0 (excess
supply) for Walras’s Law to hold
35
Walras’s Law
Proof of Walras’s Law
Involves adding up households’ budget constraints and rearranging
terms
Consider Friday’s budget constraint, where the right-hand
side is Friday’s income, represented as value of Friday’s
endowments of x1 and x2
• Total expenditures on x1 and x2 will equal this value of endowments
Rearranging terms, we get
36
Walras’s Law
Define Friday’s excess demands for commodities 1
and 2 as
For z1F > 0 Friday has excess demand for fish and z1F < 0
Friday has excess supply
Represent Friday’s budget constraint as
Value of Friday’s excess demand for the two
commodities is zero
37
Walras’s Law
Robinson’s value of excess demand for the two
commodities is also zero
Adding Friday’s and Robinson’s value of excess
demand functions yields Walras’s Law
38
Relative Prices
Important result of Walras’s Law
If aggregate demand equals aggregate supply in
one market, then, for a two-market economy
• Demand must equal supply in the other market
Generalizing to k commodities, if aggregate
demand equals aggregate supply in (k - 1)
markets
• Demand must equal supply in remaining excluded
market
39
Relative Prices
By Walras’s Law, if p2* > 0, then
A set of prices where aggregate demand for one market equals aggregate
supply will result in other market clearing
Mathematically, this implies (k - 1) independent equations in a kcommodity model
With one less equation than k number of market clearing prices, cannot
solve system for a set of k independent prices
• Can determine only relative prices
Specifically, in general equilibrium, each household’s income is the value of
endowment at given prices
• Each household’s budget constraint is homogeneous of degree zero in prices
• In general equilibrium, only relative prices are determined, given that all
•
households’ budget constraints are homogeneous of degree zero in prices
Multiplying all prices by some positive constant does not change households’
demand and supply for commodities
40
Social Welfare
Walrasian equilibrium may not be an optimal social-welfare point
However, does result in a Pareto-efficient allocation
Assumes a given distribution of initial endowments
If endowments are distributed in such a way that one agent receives a
relatively small share of initial endowments and other agent receives a
relatively large share
Social welfare may not be maximized
• To accomplish optimal distribution of initial endowments along with competitive
prices is required
One criticism of perfect competition (capitalist markets in general)
involves
Restriction that perfectly competitive markets take this distribution of initial
endowments as given
With any initial distribution of endowments that society deems as “unfair”
• Perfect competition will not maximize social welfare
41
Equitable Distribution of
Endowments and Fair Allocations
Problem of determining an optimal distribution of initial
endowments is normative in nature
Involves value judgments concerning satisfaction households
receive from their endowments
• Possible normative solution is an optimal distribution of initial
endowments that is equitable
May be defined as an allocation of endowments where no household prefers
any other household’s initial endowment
One equitable allocation of initial endowments is an equal
division of commodities
Each household has same initial commodity bundle
• Equal division will probably not be Pareto efficient
A competitive market, given this initial equal division of commodities, will
yield a Walrasian equilibrium that is Pareto efficient
Such a market allocation is called a fair allocation
Both equitable and Pareto efficient
42
Equitable Distribution of
Endowments and Fair Allocations
Can show a fair allocation resulting from a
competitive reallocation of equitable initial
endowments by contradiction
Assume allocation is not fair and Robinson is envious
• Prefers Friday’s allocation to his own
• Robinson cannot afford Friday’s allocation
• However, equal distribution of initial endowments implies value of
initial endowment must be the same
• Thus, Friday also cannot afford her optimal allocation
Results in a contradiction
43
Equitable Distribution of
Endowments and Fair Allocations
Impossible for Robinson to envy Friday at Pareto-efficient allocation
So a competitive equilibrium from equitable initial endowments is a fair
allocation
Some societies have achieved this equal division in value of initial
endowments by reducing size of Edgeworth box
Through war, pestilence, and famine, current and future generations of
households within these societies are or will be at a near subsistence level
• Social welfare is not maximized by achieving an equitable distribution of
endowments
One problem with achieving an equal distribution of initial endowment
values is
Incentives to work and invest are reduced
• No incentive to provide next generation with additional endowments
In a communist society, working for the common good is meant to
replace these individual incentives
Results in an enlargement of Edgeworth box for all comrades
• This degree of altruism may be too much to ask of individual households
44
Equitable Distribution of
Endowments and Fair Allocations
An alternative to an equal distribution of value of
endowments
Providing equal opportunities for enriching a household’s
endowments
Equal opportunity was one of driving forces for
large migration of households to United States in
19th century
Providing an initial endowment consisting of equal
opportunities is an equitable allocation
Provides an underlying justification for equal opportunity
legislation
• Ranging from minority rights to funding for public education
45
Equitable Distribution of
Endowments and Fair Allocations
U.S. history indicates that combining equal
opportunity with free markets can greatly enlarge
Edgeworth box
Results in increasing all households’ utilities and in fair
allocations leading to an optimal social-welfare allocation
of commodities
• However, a great deal of poverty still exists within United States
• The reversal in 1980s of a more equal distribution of wealth
indicates that United States has not reached local bliss
(maximum social welfare)
• Other societies are generally more socialistic than United States
Unwilling to have such a large inequality in wealth
Generally strive for a more equal distribution of endowments
• Which system is preferred is a value judgment
46