Algorithmic Mechanism Design

Download Report

Transcript Algorithmic Mechanism Design

Local Connection Game
Introduction



Introduced in [FLMPS,PODC’03]
A LCG is a game that models the creation of
networks
two competing issues: players want



to minimize the cost they incur in building the network
to ensure that the network provides them with a high
quality of service
Players are nodes that:


pay for the links
benefit from short paths
[FLMPS,PODC’03]:
A. Fabrikant, A. Luthra, E. Maneva, C.H. Papadimitriou, S. Shenker,
On a network creation game, PODC’03
The model



n players: nodes in a graph to be built
Strategy for player u: a set of undirected
edges that u will build (all incident to u)
Given a strategy vector S, the constructed
network will be G(S)


there is the undirected edge (u,v) if it is bought by
u or v (or both)
player u’s goal:


to make the distance to other nodes small
to pay as little as possible
The model



Each edge costs 
distG(S)(u,v): length of a shortest path (in
terms of number of edges) between u and v
Player u aims to minimize its cost:
costu(S) = nu +

v distG(S)(u,v)
nu: number of edges bought by node u
Remind




We use Nash equilibrium (NE) as the solution concept
To evaluate the overall quality of a network, we
consider the social cost, i.e. the sum of all players’
costs
a network is optimal or socially efficient if it
minimizes the social cost
A graph G=(V,E) is stable (for a value ) if there
exists a strategy vector S such that:


S is a NE
S forms G
Example
2
-1 3
-3
4
1
+
2
1
u

cu=+13
cu=2+9
(Convention: arrow from the node buying the link)
Example

Set =5, and consider:
+2
-2
-1
-5
-1
+2
-1
+5
+5
+5
-5
+4
+1
-1
-5
-5
+1
That’s a stable network!
Some simple observations



In SC(S) each term distG(S)(u,v) contributes to the
overall quality twice
In a stable network each edge (u,v) is bough at
most by one player
Any stable network must be connected

Since the distance dist(u,v) is infinite whenever u and v
are not connected
Social cost of a (stable) network G(S)=(V,E):
SC(S)=|E| + u,vdistG(S)(u,v)
Our goal


to bound the efficiency loss resulting from
stability
In particular:


To bound the Price of Stability (PoS)
To bound the Price of Anarchy (PoA)
How does an optimal
network look like?
Some notation
Kn: complete graph
with n nodes
A star is a tree
with height at most 1
(when rooted at its
center)
Lemma
Il ≤2 then the complete graph is an optimal solution,
while if ≥2 then any star is an optimal solution.
proof
Let G=(V,E) be an optimal solution;
|E|=m and SC(G)=OPT
OPT≥ m + 2m + 2(n(n-1) -2m) =(-2)m + 2n(n-1)
LB(m)
Notice: LB(m) is equal to SC(Kn) when m=n(n-1)/2
and to SC of any star when m=n-1
proof
G=(V,E): optimal solution;
|E|=m and SC(G)=OPT
LB(m)=(-2)m + 2n(n-1)
≥ 2
min m
LB(n-1) = SC of any star
OPT≥ min LB(m) ≥
m
≤ 2
max m
LB(n(n-1)/2) = SC(Kn)
Are the complete graph
and stars stable?
Lemma
If ≤1 the complete graph is stable, while if ≥1 then
any star is stable.
proof
≤1
a node v cannot improve
by saving k edges
≥1
c has no interest to deviate
v buys k more edges…
…pays k more…
…saves (w.r.t
distances) k…
v
c
Theorem
For ≤1 and ≥2 the PoS is 1. For 1<<2 the PoS is at
most 4/3
proof
≤1 and ≥2 …trivial!
1<<2
…Kn is an optimal solution, any star T is stable…
maximized when   1
PoS ≤
SC(T)
SC(Kn)
-1(n-1) + 2n(n-1)
(-2)(n-1) + 2n(n-1)
=  n(n-1)/2 + n(n-1) ≤ n(n-1)/2 + n(n-1)
2n - 1
4n -2
= (3/2)n = 3n
< 4/3
What about price of
Anarchy?
…for <1 the complete graph is the
only stable network,
(try to prove that formally)
hence PoA=1…
…for larger value of ?
Some more notation
The diameter of a graph G
is the maximum distance
between any two nodes
diam=2
diam=1
diam=4
Some more notation
An edge e is a cut edge of a
graph G=(V,E) if
G-e is disconnected
G-e=(V,E\{e})
A simple property:
Any graph has at
most n-1 cut
edges
Theorem
The PoA is at most O( ).
proof
It follows from the following lemmas:
Lemma 1
The diameter of any stable network is at most 2 +1 .
Lemma 2
The SC of any stable network with diameter d is at most
O(d) times the optimum SC.
proof of Lemma 1
G: stable network
Consider a shortest path in G between two nodes u and v
u
v
2k≤ distG(u,v) ≤ 2k+1
for some k
…since G is stable:
≥k2
k ≤ 
distG(u,v) ≤ 2  + 1
k vertices reduce
their distance
from u
from ≥2k to 1
 ≥ 2k-1
from ≥2k-1 to 2
 ≥ 2k-3
●
●
●
from ≥ k+1 to k
 ≥1
k-1

(2i+1)=k2
i=0
Lemma 2
The SC of any stable network G=(V,E) with diameter d is
at most O(d) times the optimum SC.
idea of the proof (we’ll formally prove it later)
OPT ≥  (n-1)
OPT = (n2)
OPT ≥  (n-1) + n(n-1)
SC(G)= u,vdG(u,v) +  |E|
≤OPT
=u,vdG(u,v) +
|Ecut|
O(d n2) = O(d) OPT
≤(n-1)
O(d) OPT
+
|Enon-cut|
O(n2d/)
=O(d) OPT
that’s the
tricky
bound
Proposition 1
Let G be a network with diameter d, and let e=(u,v) be a
non-cut edge. Then in G-e, every node w increases its
distance from u by at most 2d
…which will imply…
Proposition 2
Let G be a stable network, and let F be the set of
Non-cut edges paid for by a node u. Then |F|≤(n-1)2d/
Lemma 2
The SC of any stable network G=(V,E) with diameter d is
at most O(d) times the optimum SC.
proof
OPT ≥  (n-1) + n(n-1)
SC(G)= u,vdG(u,v) +  |E| ≤d OPT+2d OPT= 3d OPT
≤dn(n-1) ≤d OPT
|E|=|Ecut| + |Enon-cut| ≤(n-1)+n(n-1)2d ≤ 2d OPT
≤(n-1)
≤n(n-1)2d/
Prop. 2
Theorem
It is NP-hard, given the strategies of the other agents,
to compute the best response of a given player.
proof
Reduction from dominating set problem
Dominating Set (DS) problem

Input:


Solution:


a graph G=(V,E)
UV, such that for
every vV-U, there
is uU with (u,v)E
Measure:

Cardinality of U
1<<2
the reduction
player i
G=(V,E) = G(S-i)
Player i has a strategy yielding a cost  k+2n-k if and
only if there is a DS of size  k
1<<2
the reduction
player i
G=(V,E) = G(S-i)
( )
easy: given a dominating set U of size k, player i buys
edges incident to the nodes in U
Cost for i is k+2(n-k)+k =k+2n-k
1<<2
player i
x
the reduction
G=(V,E) = G(S-i)
( )
Let Si be a strategy giving a cost  k+2n-k
Modify Si as follows:
repeat:
if there is a node v such with distance ≥3 from x in
G(S), then add edge (x,v) to Si (this decreases the
cost)
1<<2
player i
x
the reduction
G=(V,E) = G(S-i)
( )
Let Si be a strategy giving a cost  k+2n-k
Modify Si as follows:
repeat:
if there is a node v such with distance ≥3 from x in
G(S), then add edge (x,v) to Si (this decreases the
cost)
Finally, every node has distance either 1 or 2 from x
1<<2
player i
x
the reduction
G=(V,E) = G(S-i)
( )
Let Si be a strategy giving a cost  k+2n-k
Modify Si as follows:
repeat:
if there is a node v such with distance ≥3 from x in
G(S), then add edge (x,v) to Si (this decreases the
cost)
Finally, every node has distance either 1 or 2 from x
Let U be the set of nodes at distance 1 from x…
1<<2
player i
x
the reduction
G=(V,E) = G(S-i)
( )
…U is a dominating set of the original graph G
We have costi(S)= |U|+2n-|U|  k+2n-k
|U|  k