A unified approach to learning spatial real estate

Download Report

Transcript A unified approach to learning spatial real estate

A unified approach to learning
spatial real estate economics
Daniel Gat
Center for Urban and Regional Studies
at the Technion
[email protected]
A Naïve Model of Housing in a Mono-Centric City
Begin with some well known assumptions:
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
City in a featureless plain
Radial travel only to a single center where everyone works and shops,
so location is a single parameter x, the home to work distance
No travel congestion so household travel costs T(x) = tau*x,
All households are identical and with equal wage y and tastes
Tastes are reflected by the household welfare function u whose
arguments are (a) housing consumption h, measured in sqm of home
area, and (b) all other consumption measured by residual income z
after rent and commuting costs
(eq. 1)
u  u ( hsg , other consumption location )
 u( h, z x )  h z1
Optimal Consumption
Given Cobb Douglas, household-welfare is maximized when housing
expenditures and other expenditures respectively equal
(eq.2)
hsg _ pmt    [ y  T ( x )]
nonhsg _ pmt  (1   )  [ y  T ( x )]
Let R(x) be the unit rent. Plugging equation (2) into (1) we get

 ( y   x) 
  (1   )(1 ) ( y   x )
1
u
(1   )( y   x) 

R ( x )
 R( x ) 
But welfare is equal across all households at all locations
(assumption 4) including at the center where there are no travel
expenses. This yields the rent gradient equation:
1
(eq.3)
1
 T ( x) 
  x 
R( x )  R0 1 
 R0 1  

y 
y


Housing Consumption and Distance
Housing expenditures are
(eq. 4)
h( x ) 
   y   x
R( x )
h  R( x )     y   x 

   y   x )
y 

 .
1

R
[
y


x
]

0
x
1
1

R0  1  
y

In other words, given income y, travel costs tau and bid rent R(x),
optimal housing size (in sqm) grows with distance from the
single center, and the function h(x) is convex.
What about the consumption of land for housing as a function of
distance?
Land consumption in the housing production process
Floor space F is produced by combining land L (measured in sqms)
with non land resources (capital measured in money units) C,
according to the function
(eq. 5)
F  AL C 1 
Where A is the overall productivity.
Floor area Ratio FAR is known as the amount of floor space per unit of site
area. Using (5):
1 
(eq. 6)
F
C
FAR   A  
L
L
 C   FAR 
  

L
A
  

1
1 
Equation 5 always holds whether production is optimal or not. Let
be the
unit price of land. Since resources are sunk in the process of building,
 the
price of building is 1. (At this point, the time to market is ignored, to be revisited later on).
Land consumption in production (continued 2/3)
Optimality yields the following results:
 L  VF
C  (1   )VF
(eq. 7)
Where V is the unit price of the finished floor area. V is related to R
through:
R
V

Where  is the capitalization rate. Divide the rows of 7 to get
(eq. 8)
L
C


1 
(1   )
C 
  

L
From (7a) we get
(eq. 9)
F

FAR  
L V
Land consumption in production (continued 3/3)
Combining (6) and (8) we get
1 
 1  
FAR  A 

  
(eq. 10)
From (7a):
  V  FAR
(eq, 11)
Combining (9) and (11), we end up after some algebra with lambda star, the
optimal unit value of land given that we know V, the value of floor space or its
corresponding rent R.
   (1   )
*
(eq.12)
1 

. AV 
1
We see that  is a convex function of V. In fact, since beta is empirically
around 1/3, is related to the 3rd power of V, so that small movements in the
price of floor-space can lead to large movements in land value. Hence,
probably, one of the reasons real estate development firms are highly volatile.
(That is definitely the case in Israel).
*
Optimal Floor Area Ratio FAR*
Optimal value of land is of course contingent on building at the optimal FAR
whose value can be computed by plugging lambda star back into equation
(10) above, thus
1 
 1  
FAR*  A  *
 


 A   (1   )

1 

 AV 
1 
1

1  
 
Which simplifies into
(eq. 13)
1 
FAR*  A (1   )V 
1

.
So optimal floor area is roughly related to the square of V.
Now we know from equation (3) that rent is negatively related to distance.
Therefore, so is the price V:
1
(eq.14)
1
 T ( x) 
  x 
V ( x )  V0 1 
 V0 1  

y 
y


Optimal Land Value and Floor Area Ratio FAR*
Related to Distance from CBD
By plugging (14) into (2) and (13) we get the expressions for Lambda star
an FAR star as functions of x, the distance between home and CBD.
1
 *   (1   )
1 

 T ( x )  
( AV0 ) 1 

y


1

1 
(eq. 15)
FAR*  A  (1   )V0 
1

1 

 T ( x )  
1  y 


Note that both the distance gradients of the unit value of land and that of
the optimal FAR have become considerably steeper. ( 1    in the
denominator ). This reflects two trade-offs, that of area for distance by the
consumer and that of capital for land by the producer; both trade-offs
display diminishing returns to size. Note also use of the general term T(x)
and not the specific x times tau. This will be useful soon.
End of the Naïve Mono-Centric Model.
Interim Conclusions
This naïve model even with its crude assumptions is agood first introduction
to urban land economics. Although the demand section is about housing, the
model is also a launching platform for understanding non-housing land use
since any use needs to compete with housing which which in all cities
dominates the landscape.
The variations which I have developed – but won’t show here – include:
• Quality of the building and a link to Hedonics
• Automotive travel congestion and a multi mode city
• Variety of household types, e.g. “space seekers” and “action seekers”
• Time to market and the substitution of NPV for profit as the maximand
• Redevelopment by demolition (optimal and constrained by zoning)
• Urban quasi-dynamics of a city with long lived but replaceable buildings
The variation that I would like to peek at, just to show how far this model will
take us is:
“Going from Mono to Poly”
Going from Mono to Poly
The switch is absolutely simple. The only major assumption that needs
to be changed is that of a single center. In the poly version a set of
centers is defined by specifying size and coordinates of each center.
Given a city with several centers entails 3 modifications:
(1) Location is no longer a single number x. Instead, it is x = (x1, x2), a
vector of the two coordinates.
(2) The consumer now has to decide how to allocate its trips between
alternative destinations. We know how to do that – using a discrete
choice probability model and then averaging.
(3) The result is the expected monthly vehicle miles ensuing from a
household at each location (x1, x2). Multiply by that by the unit cost
of travel and we have T(x). Plug T(x) into the rent equation (3) and
the others that follow, and we are home free.
Instead of going through the formal equations I will show you some 3 D graphic
results of simulating the polycentric model, (rent, land value and optimal FAR when
income is set at 3, 4 an 5 k dollars per month) and then compare these results with
some figures from the literature.
Literature Examples
Berry 1963: polycentered
chicago commercial structure
Bernick and Cervero 1997:
Bay area employment densities
Alonso 1964: a city
model with two centers
Romano 1972:
a city model with two centers
Cervero 1998:
Sketch model of adaptive city
Redfearn 2006:
Semi-parametric model of Krakow