Transcript App 6

A Lecture Presentation
in PowerPoint
to accompany
Exploring Economics
Second Edition
by Robert L. Sexton
Copyright © 2002 Thomson Learning, Inc.
Thomson Learning™ is a trademark used herein under license.
ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. Instructors of classes adopting EXPLORING ECONOMICS, Second Edition by Robert L.
Sexton as an assigned textbook may reproduce material from this publication for classroom use or in a secure electronic
network environment that prevents downloading or reproducing the copyrighted material. Otherwise, no part of this work
covered by the copyright hereon may be reproduced or used in any form or by any means—graphic, electronic, or
mechanical, including, but not limited to, photocopying, recording, taping, Web distribution, information networks, or
information storage and retrieval systems—without the written permission of the publisher.
Printed in the United States of America
ISBN 0030342333
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
A More Advanced Theory of
Consumer Choice
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Indifference Curves

What Is an Indifference Curve?
A consumer’s indifference curve contains
various combinations of two commodities
and each combination of goods (like points
A, B, and C) on the indifference curve will
yield the same level of total utility to this
consumer.
 The consumer is said to be indifferent
between any combination of the two goods
along an individual indifference curve,
because the consumer receives the same
level of satisfaction from each bundle.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.

Quantity of Clothing
Exhibit 1 An Indifference Curve
A
B
C
Indifference
Curve
0
Quantity of Food
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Properties of the
Indifference Curve

Four properties of indifference curves




higher indifference curves represent
greater satisfaction
are negatively sloped
cannot intersect
are convex from the origin
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Properties of the
Indifference Curve

Higher indifference curves represent
greater satisfaction

Although equally happy with any bundle of
goods along the indifference curve,
consumers prefer to be on the highest
indifference curve possible.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Quantity of Clothing
Exhibit 2 Indifference Curves
A
D
B
C
0
Quantity of Food
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
I0
I1
The Properties of the Indifference
Curve

Consumer would prefer I2 to I1.


Bundle D gives the consumer more of both
goods than bundle C, which is on a lower
indifference curve.
Bundle D is also preferred to bundle A
because there is more than enough extra
food to compensate the consumer for the
loss of clothing; his total utility has risen.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Properties of the
Indifference Curve

Indifference curves are negatively
sloped

must slope downward from left to right

If both goods are desirable and the quantity of
one good is reduced, the quantity of the other
good must be increased to maintain the same
level of total satisfaction.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Properties of the
Indifference Curve

Indifference curves cannot intersect


Each curve represents various
combinations that yield a given level of
satisfaction.
If they did intersect, then it would violate
the assumption that more of a good is
preferred to less of a good.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Indifference Curves Cannot Intersect
Quantity of Clothing
C
B
A
0
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Quantity of Food
I0
I1
The Properties of the
Indifference Curve

The consumer is indifferent between
bundle A and bundle B (both on
indifference curve I0) but is also indifferent
between bundle A and bundle C (both on
indifference curve I1). But how could this be
correct if bundle C has more of both goods
than bundle B? In other words, this violates
the assumption that more is preferred to
less, and therefore indifference curves
cannot intersect.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Properties of the Indifference
Curve

Indifference curves are convex from the
origin

The slope of the indifference curve reflects
the marginal rate of substitution.

the rate at which a consumer is willing to trade
one good to gain one more unit of another
good
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Properties of the Indifference
Curve

If the indifference curve is steep, the
marginal rate of substitution is high.

The consumer would be willing to give up a
large amount of A for a small amount of B.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Quantity of Clothing
Indifference Curves Are Convex from
the Origin
A
20
5
MRS = 5
15
10
5
4
0
1
MRS = 5
B
Indifference
1
Curve
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Quantity of Food
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Properties of the
Indifference Curve


If the indifference curve is flatter, the
marginal rate of substitution is low.
The consumer is only willing to give up a
small amount of A in exchange for an
additional unit of B to remain indifferent

If you have lots of something, you will not value
the prospect of getting even more of it more
highly; this is just the law of demand, which is
based on the law of diminishing marginal utility.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Properties of the
Indifference Curve

Complements

use of more units of one encourages the
acquisition of additional units of the other.
gasoline and automobiles
 baseballs and baseball bats
 snow skis and bindings
 bread and butter
 coffee and cream


When complements, units of one good
cannot be acquired without affecting the
want-satisfying power of other goods.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Properties of the
Indifference Curve

Substitutes

The more you have of one, the less your
desire the other.
coffee and tea
 sweaters and jackets
 home-cooked and restaurant meals

Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Properties of the
Indifference Curve

The degree of convexity of an
indifference curve—that is, the extent to
which the curve deviates from a straight
line—depends on how easily the two
goods can be substituted for each other.

Perfect substitutes, the indifference curve
is a straight line (in this case of slope –1).
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Properties of the
Indifference Curve

Perfect complements, goods are never
used separately but are consumed only
together.


left and right shoes.
Since it is impossible to replace units of
one with units of the other and maintain
satisfaction, the marginal rate of
substitution is undefined; thus, the
indifference curve is a right angle
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Perfect Substitutes and
Perfect Complements
6
Left Shoes
$10 Bills
3
2
1
I0
0
2
I1
4
$5 Bills
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
I2
6
5
B
4
C
3
A
2
1
0
1
2 3 4 5 6
Right Shoes
I1
I0
The Properties of the
Indifference Curve


If two commodities can easily be
substituted for one another, the nearer
the indifference curves will approach a
straight line
The greater the complementarity
between the two goods, the nearer the
indifference curves will approach a right
angle.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Budget Line

A budget line represents the various
combinations of two goods that a
consumer can buy with a given income,
holding the prices of the two goods
constant.


the horizontal axis measures the quantity
of clothing
the vertical axis measures the quantity of
food.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Budget Line


Moving along the budget line, we can
see the various combinations of food
and clothing the consumer can
purchase with her income.
Any combination of goods beyond the
budget line is not feasible.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Budget Line
Quantity of Clothing
Y
10 A
8
6
4
Income = $50
PX (Food) = $10
PY (Clothing) = $5
B
Not
Affordable
C
D
2
E
Affordable
0
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Budget
Line
F
1 2 3 4 5
Quantity of Food
X
The Budget Line

Finding the X- and Y-intercepts of the
budget line

The intercept can easily be found by
dividing the total income available for
expenditures by the price of the good in
question.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Budget Line: Intercepts and Slopes
Quantity of Clothing
Y
10
8
(Income/PY = $50/$5 = 10)
Income = $50
PX (Food) = $10
PY (Clothing) = $5
6
4
Budget Line
2
(Income/PX = $50/$10 = 5)
X
0
1 2 3 4 5
Quantity of Food
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
The Budget Line

Finding the Slope of the Budget Line


The slope of the budget line is equal to
-PX/PY.
The negative coefficient of the slope
indicates that the budget line is negatively
sloped (downward sloping), reflecting the
fact that you must give up some of one
good to get more of the other.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Consumer Optimization

Given the consumer’s indifference
curves for two goods, together with the
budget line showing the various
quantities of the two that can be
purchased with a given money income
for expenditure, the optimal (or best)
quantities of each good to be purchased
can be determined.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Consumer Optimization

Income-consumption curve (ICC)

a curve that connects the various optimum
combinations of two goods as a
consumer’s income changes
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Quantity of Clothing
Point of Tangency—The Consumer’s Optimal
12
10
8
B
A
6
C
I2
4
Budget
2 Line
0
1
2
I1
I0
3
4
5
Quantity of Food
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
6
Consumer Optimization

The optimum occurs where the budget
line is tangent to indifference curve I1, at
point A.


To maximize satisfaction, the consumer
must acquire the most preferred attainable
bundle, that is, reach the highest
indifference curve that can be reached with
a given level of income.
The highest curve that can be reached is
the one to which the budget line is tangent,
at point A.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Changes in the Budget Line

The position of the budget line if income
rises

An increase in income, holding relative
prices constant, will cause the curve to
shift out parallel to the old curve.

a richer person can afford more of both goods
than a poorer person because of the higher
budget line.
The change in income, holding relative
prices constant, is called the income effect
and it causes this parallel shift in the
budget
line.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.

Quantity of Clothing
A Change In Income
Richer
An Increase
in Income
Poorer
L0
Quantity of Food
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
L1
Changes in the Budget Line

With a given pattern of indifference
curves, larger amounts available for
spending will result in an income
consumption curve (ICC) connecting the
best consumption points (tangencies) at
each income level.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Changes in the Budget Line

The rise in income shifts the budget line
outward.


If both goods are normal goods in this
range, then the consumer will buy more of
both goods
If income rises and the consumer buys less
of one good, we say that good is an inferior
good.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
B
A
I1
L0
0
Income
Consumption
Curve
I0
B
Income
Consumption
Curve
I1
A
I0
L0
L1
Quantity of Food
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Quantity of Clothing
Quantity of Clothing
Change in Income
0
L1
Quantity of Low-Quality Meat
Changes in the Budget Line

Budget line reflects price changes


Purchases depend on relative prices as
well as income level.
When the price of one good changes,
holding income and the price of the other
good constant, it causes a relative price
effect.

Relative prices affect the way the consumers
allocates their income among different goods.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Changes in the Budget Line


A price change of the good on either the Yor X-axis causes the budget line to rotate
inward or outward from the intercept on the
other axis.
This fall in price expands consumers’
buying opportunities—rotating the budget
line outward
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Quantity of Clothing
Change in the Relative Price of Food
10 A
Income = $50
Price of Food
Rises from $10 to $25
Price of Food
Rises from
$10 to $5
L2
0
L0
L1
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Quantity of Hamburger
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Changes in the Budget Line

The tangency relationship between the
budget line and the indifference curve
indicates the optimal amounts of each
of the two goods the consumer will
purchase, given


the prices of both goods and
the consumer’s total available income for
expenditures.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Changes in the Budget Line


At different possible prices for one of
the goods, given the price of the other
and given total income, a consumer
would optimally purchase different
quantities of the two goods.
A change in the price of one of the
goods will alter the slope of the budget
line because a different amount of the
good can be purchased with a given
level of income.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
L0 Budget Line,
Price of $5 for clothing.
$10 for food.
L1 Budget Line,
Price of $5 for clothing.
$5 for food.
Income = $5 for food.
A
B
I2
I1
I0
L0
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
A
$10
B
5
Demand
for Food
L1
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Quantity of Food
Price of Food
Quantity of Clothing
The Price Consumption Curve
0
2
5
Quantity of Food
Changes in the Budget Line

The point of tangency moves from A to
B as a result of the decline in price of
food from $10 to $5; the equilibrium
quantity of food purchased increases
from two to five units.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Changes in the Budget Line


Price-consumption curve (PCC): a
curve consisting of the various optimum
combinations of two goods as the
relative price of one good changes
The price-consumption curve (PCC)
may be drawn through these points of
tangency, indicating the optimum
quantities at various possible prices of
food (given the price of clothing).
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.
Changes in the Budget Line


From this price-consumption curve can
be derived the usual demand curve for
the good.
Essentially, the demand curve is made
up of various price and quantity
optimum points.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc.