Transcript 100 €1.00

Ecological Economics
Lecture 09
20th May 2010
Tiago Domingos
Assistant Professor
Environment and Energy Section
Department of Mechanical Engineering
Collaboration: Rui Pedro Mota
[email protected]
Temporal Comparison - Real vs Nominal
• What part of the change in national accounts aggregates at current prices
stems from a change in the quantities produced and what part stems from
a change in prices?
Nominal GDP in:
Item
- 2007, €200
2007
- 2008, €575
Quantity
Price
Bread
100
€1.00
Real GDP in 2007 prices:
Butter
20
€5.00
- 2007, €200
2008
Bread
160
€ 0.50
Butter
22
€ 22.50
- 2008, €270
Price Level
GDP Deflator
Price Level and GDP deflator
• Nominal and real GDP are calculated as shown above.
• GDP Deflatoryear x = (Nominal GDPyear x ÷ Real GDPyear x ) * 100.
Year
Nominal GDP
Real GDP
GDP deflator
2007
€200
€200
100
2008
€575
€250
230
• Nominal GDP increases because production increases and because prices
increase (Inflation).
• Use the GDP deflator to take out the effect of inflation and reveal real GDP.
• The Base year for current SNA is 2000.
• Inflation rate = rate of change of price level, 130% = (230-100)/100*100
Real vs. Nominal (Portugal)
200
Milliards euros
180
160
Gross domestic product at 2000
market prices
140
Gross domestic product at
current market prices
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
1960
1965
Source: AMECO database
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
Price Level and CPI
• Consumer Price Index (CPI)
– It is based on a fixed (changes every 5 years) basket of goods that are
normally an important part of households’ consumption.
• 1 – Fix the Basket - which prices are most important to the typical consumer? Put
weights by surveying consumers and finding the basket of goods and services that the
typical consumer buys.
• 2 – Find the prices for each good and service in the basket.
• 3 – Compute the basket’s cost (price * quantity)
• 4 – Choose a base year and compute the CPI Formula
• 5 – Compute inflation as the rate of change in CPI
CPI and Inflation
GDP deflator vs CPI
• Both reflect the current level of prices relative to the level of prices in the
base year.
GDP Deflator
CPI
-Prices of all goods and
services produced
domestically.
-Prices of all goods and
services bought by
consumers.
- Compares the price of
currently produced goods.
- Compares a fixed basket
of goods and services.
GDP deflator vs CPI (Portugal)
Inflation
35
Oil Price shock, 1973
30
25
20
%
CPI
GDP Deflator
15
10
5
0
1964
1969
1974
Source: AMECO database and UN data
1979
1984
1989
1994
1999
2004
Calvin and Hobbes on time preference
• What is more valuable: enjoyment now or later?
– Time preference or discount rate is the rate at which the agent is willing to postpone
consumption.
• Is Calvin’s discount rate high or low, with regard to smacking Susie?
– The role of uncertainty and sunk costs.
Calvin and Hobbes on time preference
• Very high discount rate is not prudent.
• In the presence of uncertainty, discount the future at its lowest possible
rate. (Weitzman, 1998 JEEM)
Discounted Utilitarianism
• Representative household’s welfare at time t

W (t )   u(c( s ))e
t
   s t 
u ''(c )  0  u '(c )
ds
– Utility depends on present consumption bundle.
– Welfare depends on the present and future utilities.
• Discount factor: €1 in T periods from now, is worth exp(−rT ) today.
Same applies to utility.
• In discrete time,

W (t )  
s t
u(cs )
1   
s t
•  is the utility discount rate, i.e., the rate at which the value of a small
increment of utility changes as its date is delayed.
Discounted Utilitarianism Ramsey Model
• Ouput is produced using capital and labor (Assume a constant population
normalized to 1). Capital does not depreciate. There is no technological
progress.
• The output is either consumed or invested, i.e., added to the capital stock
(as in Solow’s model)
f (k )  c  k
• The social planner (benevolent dictator) chooses how much the
representative household should consume/invest (add to capital to
provide consumption in future)

max  u(c )e t dt
c
s.t.
0
k  f ( k )  c   k , k ( 0)  k 0  0
Discounted Utilitarianism Ramsey Model
• Any solution (k (t ), c (t ))
*
*

0
must obey:
1 dc* 1 ' *
du ' ( c ) c
 - Instantaneous elasticity
  f (k )    ,   
*
'
c dt 
dc u ( c )
of substitution between
consumption in two dates
dk *
*
*
 f (k )  c ,
k ( 0)  k 0  0
dt
lim u ' ( c* ( t ))k * ( t )e   t  0
t 
• If the interest rate is the marginal productivity of capital, then the
Ramsey rules rewrites as
r   g
Discounted Utilitarianism
• Elasticity of substitution between consumption at two points in time t
and s, is given by
d  cs ct 
u ' (cs ) u ' (ct )
 (c )  
cs ct
d u ' (cs ) u ' (ct )


• Taking the limit as s converges to t, it is obtained the inverse of the
negative elasticity of marginal utility
1
 du ' (c ) c 
1
 (c )   


'
dc
u
(
c
)



• The larger the elasticity the easier it is to forgo current consumption.
Ramsey Rule
r   g
• Ro – Discount rate. Used to compare the welfare of generations living in
different times.
• h – Curvature of utility function. Aversion to inequality across/within
generations.
– How peoples’ wellbeing changes as income increases.
– Large h means larger aversion to intertemporal inequality.
• Ro and h depend on peoples’ preferences.
• G is related to economic growth and technological progress.
Ramsey Rule with technology (Barro and Sala-i-Martin, p. 97)
dK
dk
 F ( K , AL)  C   K 
 f (k )  c  (n  x   )k
dt
dt
K
C
C
cˆ dA
dL
ˆ
k
, c , c
 ,
 xA,
 nL, r  f '  
AL
L
AL A dt
dt
• Consumption per unit of effective labor

r    g  x


cˆ
g
cˆ
• Consumption per capita

r   g
g
c
c
• Absolute consumption
r     G  n

C
G
C